Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

The Happiness Equation: The Surprising Economics of Our Most Valuable Asset
The Happiness Equation: The Surprising Economics of Our Most Valuable Asset
The Happiness Equation: The Surprising Economics of Our Most Valuable Asset
Ebook285 pages4 hours

The Happiness Equation: The Surprising Economics of Our Most Valuable Asset

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

Why is marriage worth £200,000 a year?

Why will having children make you unhappy?

Why does happiness from winning the lottery take two years to arrive?

Why does time heal the pain of divorce or the death of a loved one – but not unemployment?

Everybody wants to be happy. But how much happiness – precisely – will each life choice bring? Should I get married? Am I really going to feel happy about the career that I picked? How can we decide not only which choice is better for us, but how much it's better for us?

The result of new, unique research, The Happiness Equation brings to a general readership for the first time the new science of happiness economics.

It describes how we can measure emotional reactions to different life experiences and present them in ways we can relate to. How, for instance, monetary values can be put on things that can't be bought or sold in the market – such as marriage, friendship, even death – so that we can objectively rank them in order of preference. It also explains why some things matter more to our happiness than others (like why seeing friends is worth more than a Ferrari) while others are worth almost nothing (like sunny weather).

Nick Powdthavee – whose work on happiness has been discussed on both the Undercover Economist and Freakanomics blogs – brings cutting-edge research on how we value our happiness to a general audience, with a style that wears its learning lightly and is a joy to read.
LanguageEnglish
PublisherIcon Books
Release dateAug 5, 2010
ISBN9781848312241
The Happiness Equation: The Surprising Economics of Our Most Valuable Asset

Related to The Happiness Equation

Related ebooks

Social Science For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for The Happiness Equation

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    The Happiness Equation - Nick Powdthavee

    CHAPTER 1

    THE PURSUIT

    Most of us go through life believing we know exactly what we need to make us happy. For the most part, we believe that all we ever need is to have someone we love loving us back. Or it’s a combination of more money, a good job, a stable marriage and perfect health. Sometimes it’s the little things in life, like a day off work; a clear blue sky on an autumn afternoon; a nice cup of cool mochaccino on a hot day; an hour-long foot rub; a day spent laughing with friends and family; 45 minutes of uninterrupted sex with our partner, and the energy to last for the best part of it.

    But unfortunately – in the words of Mick Jagger and Keith Richards – we can’t always get what we want. At least, we can’t always get what we want all the time. A day off work every so often sounds like a good idea until, of course, we realise that we will become a little poorer because of it. And that’s no good because, according to the abstract idea we have in our heads of what makes a good life, money matters a lot. Okay then, in that case, we’ll put in more hours at work. But wait. That will also mean less time to be spent with friends and family, and that doesn’t seem so good either.

    So what do we do, then? What do we do when our lives are a series of trade-offs between different combinations of ‘what ifs’? What do we do when there is an endless horizon of time and resource constraints constantly telling us that whatever we do, we can’t possibly have it all? Well, according to economists, who are supposedly experts on decision-making, what usually happens is that we try to do the best we can with our choices. We gather all necessary information about our options. We engage in rationalisation and mental calculations. We quietly argue and debate within ourselves over the potential impacts of each individual decision on our happiness. We cross-refer them to the rule-book of ‘All the things that make me happy’, put each possibility into an order of preference, and then, subject to both time and resource constraints, choose the best combination of bundles that we know would optimise our well-being.

    Easy.

    Bounded rationality

    But of course, if that were true – if we always chose the best possible combination of options according to stable preference functions and the constraints facing them – then the way we led our lives would literally be disappointment-free. Whatever decisions we made, we would know exactly well in advance what we were getting ourselves into. After all, our rationality would have already done the homework for us: we would be getting the greatest reward at the lowest cost.

    How could we possibly not be happy with that?

    The reality, however, is that our lives are too often filled with disappointing and regrettable decisions, whether big or small. The holiday we went on last summer; that antique car we bought; or even the job or college degrees we picked. The following anecdotal evidence from a chance meeting between two economists and a dentist makes it all too clear.1

    Two economics professors and friends, John Bennett and Chuck Blackorby, were attending an economics conference. On the first evening, they met a dentist at the hotel bar who was at an annual conference for dentists just next door to them. After a brief introduction and a couple of drinks, Chuck, who was known for his sometimes brash and direct manner, decided to ask the dentist, by then a little tipsy, a somewhat personal question.

    ‘So, tell me, are you very happy being a dentist?’

    ‘Happy? I’m miserable as a dentist’, replied the man.

    Chuck smiled to himself. ‘What? If you’re so unhappy, why on earth did you choose to become a dentist in the first place?’

    ‘I didn’t choose to become a dentist.’ The man took another swig of his drink before delivering the final hammer blow. ‘It’s that stupid kid eighteen years ago that chose to become a dentist. Not me.’

    And even when we’re not too disappointed; when we actually think we’re fairly satisfied with the choices we made, sometimes there’s just no way for us to know for certain whether or not we would have been happier if we’d gone with the alternatives. Take having children, for example. For most parents, a natural and genuine response to the question, ‘Would you be happier without children?’ would be a screaming ‘No!’ However, there’s no real way of knowing precisely what life would have been like if these parents had decided not to have their little David or Sarah – simply because the childless alternative didn’t take place for them. The same argument holds true for partners who choose not to become parents.

    One of the main reasons why we aren’t always able to choose the best options for ourselves is that our rationality is often bounded by the amount of information it possesses, the cognitive limitations of our brains,2 and the finite amount of time we have to make a decision.3 According to the so-called ‘bounded rationality’ concept, we human beings are only partly rational – and downright irrational in the remaining part of our actions. While economists believe that all human beings are approximately Homo economicus (economic man), rational and broadly self-interested by nature, the reality is that we are just as likely, if not more likely, to let emotions overrule rationality and completely dictate the way we behave.

    That we are not wholly rational is shown by studies that have identified two distinct sides to our brains: one that is rational – controlled, slow, deliberative and deductive; and one that is emotional – automatic, rapid, associative and affective.4 The mesh between the two is extremely complex, and one does not always dominate the other. And while economic theories of decision-making have tended to emphasise the operation of the rational side of our brain in guiding choice behaviour, it’s often the case that, when making decisions under pressure or under conditions where information is incomplete or overly complex, we tend to rely on simplifying heuristics or ‘gut feelings’ rather than extensive algorithmic processing.5 These ‘rules of thumb’ are far from perfect, and it’s precisely why we sometimes spend too much money on food when we go grocery shopping with an empty stomach,6 or find it increasingly difficult to walk away from a bus stop the longer we have been waiting for a bus to come – even if it would have been a lot quicker to walk than to wait for that damn bus to arrive.7

    The adaptive unconscious and past experiences

    But maybe it’s not always such a bad thing to trust our emotions. Research carried out by psychology professor Timothy Wilson suggests that, in situations where we have had a lot of experience, decisions made without thinking (those made on impulses and gut feelings) can often lead to better and happier outcomes than if they had been made under a strict rule of optimisation, simply because this is when the emotional part of our brain works best at detecting that something is out of the ordinary – even if we may not know ourselves what that something is at the time – and alerts us in the form of emotional alarm bells such as sweaty palms and butterflies in our stomach.8 And it’s in these scenarios that practice really makes perfect. It’s also where thinking too much about our past experiences can actually hurt rather than help us.

    The question is: Why?

    One reason. According to psychologist and Nobel laureate Daniel Kahneman, the cognitive part of our brain tends to suffer from what he called the ‘peak-end’ effect, which is the tendency to judge past experiences – both pleasant and unpleasant – almost entirely on how they were at their peak and how they ended.9

    Kahneman and his colleagues illustrated the core concept of the peak-end theory in a series of experiments, most notably that involving hospital patients and the very painful colonoscopy procedure.10 While undergoing a colonoscopy, the patients reported their level of discomfort every 60 seconds throughout the procedure. Afterwards, the patients were asked to remember how unpleasant the procedure was, using several different scales including a ten-point scale, and also about the relative unpleasantness of the colonoscopy compared to other unpleasant experiences such as stubbing a toe, or an average visit to the dentist. What Kahneman and his colleagues found was astonishing. While there was almost zero correlation between the duration of the colonoscopies that different patients experienced and the global rating of the procedure, the relationship between the peak-end average (the average of the peaks and how the patients felt at the end of the procedure) and the global rating of the procedure was simply undeniable. In other words, we are more likely to remember our experience of a colonoscopy as being awful if the peaks of unpleasantness were very high or if it ended awfully for us, than if the entire procedure itself took a long time to finish. What matters is not the duration of an experience; we hardly ever think about it when we try to recall and judge how happy or unhappy we were in the past. It’s how we were feeling at the peaks and at the end of our experience that count the most.

    What about frequency? Surely having experienced something often can teach us to repeat only the things that we remember with pleasure and fondness, and avoid those that we remember with embarrassment and regret? The trouble is, according to Harvard psychologist Daniel Gilbert, we are just not very good at remembering them correctly. He illustrates his point by prompting the readers of his book – Stumbling on Happiness – to think about where they were, whom they were with, and what they were doing when they first heard the news about the 9/11 attacks in 2001.11 Okay, that sounds easy enough. Closing my eyes, I can still remember that I was standing at one of the check-in counters at London Heathrow airport, trying to get on the evening flight to Bangkok. Sitting behind the Finnair counter was a man in his late 50s who, as I recall, spoke with a very thick Glaswegian accent.

    ‘So you’re off to Thailand then, eh? Ah, what a beautiful country! Lovely food, gorgeous beaches, very pretty women!’ His eyes twinkled as he said this.

    I smiled politely, acknowledging his appreciation of my country of birth. I knew he was just trying to be friendly in what seemed to be a surprisingly empty airport on a Tuesday afternoon.

    ‘Okay, sir. Here’s your boarding pass. Have a nice flight … Oh, and have you heard? Two planes hit the World Trade Center not half an hour ago. Probably a terrorist attack. But since you’re flying to Finland first, I’m sure you’ll be just fine.’ He ended with a beam while I stood there, rigid as a board.

    Like me, most people will be able to remember in fine detail what they were doing when they first heard the news. But, Gilbert added – would the same people also remember precisely where they were, whom they were with, and what they were doing on the morning of 10 September 2001, one day before the attacks?

    I personally couldn’t, of course. And I’m confident enough to bet that not many people could either – a fact that is also true for most Americans.

    The main reason why it’s relatively easier for us to recall the exact details of 11 September 2001, but nearly impossible to remember what happened a day earlier, is because momentous events like the 9/11 attacks do not happen frequently in our lifetime. While 11 September 2001 defied our every sense of normality, 10 September, by contrast, was like almost any other day. And unless we religiously keep a diary of everything that ever happened in our lives, any other day is nothing more than a blob in our memory bank.

    Daniel Gilbert’s message is clear: it is the infrequent and unusual experiences that are most memorable. These are the ones that stick like glue to the clipboard of our memory cortex. Not the other way round.

    Conventional wisdom and imagination

    There are two lessons we can draw at this stage. The first is that, in situations where we have had a lot of experience, it’s perhaps better to trust our instincts when it comes to making a decision. And the second lesson, related to the first, is that it seems important not to rely completely on emotions in situations where we have had little or no prior experience. The explanation is simple: in these circumstances, the emotional part of our brain will not have had enough chances to adapt and learn from our past experiences, which will inevitably make it impossible for it to distinguish which decision is better for us.12

    That sounds perfectly reasonable. All we need to do now is follow any great professional’s advice and just practise, practise, practise. Then afterwards, we can sit back in situations where we have had a lot of these experiences and just make snap decisions without having to think too much about the best outcomes.

    Two problems, though. First, how do we know when we have had enough practice doing something? How do we know when we can let the rational brain take a back seat and the emotional brain do all the work? Will 10,000 hours of doing something repetitively be enough?13 Or will it take a lifetime of experience? Second, what about other, more novel situations? How do we know that we will be happier being married than staying single? How do we know whether we will be happier in a job that pays less but is nevertheless much closer to home? How can we be sure that rationality will not fail us when we have to face dilemmas that we have never faced before?

    So now we’ve come full circle: economists’ description of how the world works – though somewhat incomplete – actually turns out to be useful advice on what we should do in situations where we have had little or no prior experience. According to theories on rational choice,14 there are perhaps two essential ingredients to successful decision-making when a degree of rationality is involved. The first is time. Unlike the emotional part of our brain where all decision-making is done instantaneously, the rational part of our brain needs time to think things over, to mull over the information. The second ingredient is getting the right information. It’s important that we have perfect awareness of all relevant information regarding the outcome of our choice before making a decision, especially one that could change our lives.

    Since we can often find time to think things over before coming up with a solution for many of our life problems, could it just be the case that we don’t always have the right information about the choices we plan to make? Going back to the unhappy dentist, could it be possible that he decided to obtain a degree in dentistry on a whim or, worse, on a dare? Maybe. Nevertheless, considering the potentially life-changing impact of choosing the right career, it’s perhaps more likely that he did try to seek all the available information about how happy a career in dentistry would make him in eighteen years’ time. How could he then have been so wrong?

    There are usually two ways of getting the information we need about the potential impacts of a novel experience. First, we can do some research about the experience. So in the case of the unhappy dentist, his decision to study dentistry could have been influenced by what he was expecting to get objectively from becoming a dentist, such as financial return, or by other people’s accounts of their subjective experiences as dentists, or even by conventional wisdom passed down from generation to generation.

    Second, if all else fails, we can still use our imagination to conjure up the information we need to undertake a decision. We can try, for example, to picture ourselves in the future: what life would be like being married, or having kids, or having so much money we don’t know what to do with it.

    The trouble – and we know it’s never going to be good news when a sentence starts with ‘The trouble’ – with these two ways of gathering the necessary information for our rational brain to digest is that both are subject to serious cognitive distortions. Take asking other people about their subjective experiences, for example. Would everybody admit, as the unhappy dentist admits after a few drinks, that they regret undertaking a decision, one that they can’t redo or undo? Not always, as it turns out. Studies in psychology suggest that people tend to rationalise the costs of their decisions – especially the ones that can’t be undone, such as parenthood or career choices – and then conclude that, given the high price they pay, they must be happy with their choices.15 In other words, we are more likely to look for and find a positive view of the things we are stuck with than of the things we are not.16

    Our very own imagination is not much better. For example, research in psychology has found that we tend to overestimate the length or the intensity of our feelings – both pleasant and unpleasant – whenever we make a prediction about our future emotional states. Daniel Gilbert and his colleagues illustrated by a series of experiments that people overestimated, by a long shot, the duration of their emotional reactions to various negative events that included, among other things, the break-up of a romantic relationship, rejection from a job interview, and an account of a child’s death.17 The psychologists attributed this so-called ‘impact bias’ to the fact that, whenever we attempt to predict our affective reactions to a particular event, we naturally focus our attention on that event to the exclusion of others.18 So, for example, in the case of Gilbert’s study, when a mother is asked to imagine what life would be like seven years after the death of her child, she is likely to focus exclusively on the tragedy and fail to consider the many other events that will also happen along the way, and which may also affect her general happiness state. Of course, it would seem absurd for any mother to pause and consider how her unhappiness might be eased by a holiday in the Bahamas, a promotion at work, or seeing a good film over that time period. But the truth is that life does go on, and the things we don’t normally think about when imagining our emotional reactions to a particular event do happen and do have affective consequences. It’s also the very reason why we often find our future selves not as happy (or unhappy) about a particular event as we thought we would be when we first imagined experiencing it.

    So our search for happiness goes on in a somewhat stumbling manner. Sometimes we learn from our past mistakes; sometimes we don’t. Sometimes we make the right decision just from asking other people about their affective experiences; sometimes we don’t. Sometimes we make a spot-on prediction about the duration and intensity of our affective reactions to a particular event; most of the time we don’t. It doesn’t matter how hard we try, there just doesn’t seem to be a formula to happiness, especially one that is scientifically credible.

    Or is there?

    The happiness equation

    This brings us to the present. What if there is a scientific way of constructing a happiness formula? What if we can, with some degree of accuracy, measure and study a typical person’s emotional reactions to different life events, and then write a complete guidebook about the average impact of each one of them on our well-being? What if there’s no need any more for us to ask other people for advice about a particular experience, or use our own imagination to picture what life would be like in the future if we made this choice and not the other? What if we could go back in time to eighteen years ago and say to that unhappy dentist-to-be: ‘Hey! Don’t become a dentist! You’re guaranteed to be miserable for life’, even if we’re not dentists ourselves? How would we react to that kind of information? What if we can actually put a value or a price on each different life event so that we know which is more worth our time, relative to the others? Will this new knowledge change anything or everything in the way we think or act?

    This book is hardly the definitive book about all the things that really make each and every one of us happy. That book doesn’t exist and probably never will. Rather, this book is about the journey towards achieving that kind of possibility; the possibility of having perfect foresight about our emotional reactions to the many different events our lives have to offer. Weaving together findings and theories from the new science of happiness, this book provides a snapshot of what the world would be

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1