Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Unavailable
Thinking, Fast and Slow
Unavailable
Thinking, Fast and Slow
Unavailable
Thinking, Fast and Slow
Audiobook20 hours

Thinking, Fast and Slow

Written by Daniel Kahneman

Narrated by Patrick Egan

Rating: 4 out of 5 stars

4/5

()

Currently unavailable

Currently unavailable

About this audiobook

The unabridged, downloadable audiobook edition of Thinking, Fast and Slow, Daniel Kahneman's pioneering work that tackles questions of intuition and rationality. Read by the actor Patrick Egan.

Daniel Kahneman, recipient of the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for his seminal work in psychology challenging the rational model of judgment and decision making, is one of the world's most important thinkers. His ideas have had a profound impact on many fields-including business, medicine, and politics-but until now, he has never brought together his many years of research in one book.

In Thinking, Fast and Slow, Kahneman takes us on a groundbreaking tour of the mind and explains the two systems that drive the way we think and make choices. One system is fast, intuitive, and emotional; the other is slower, more deliberative, and more logical. Kahneman exposes the extraordinary capabilities-and also the faults and biases-of fast thinking, and reveals the pervasive influence of intuitive impressions on our thoughts and behaviour. The importance of properly framing risks, the effects of cognitive biases on how we view others, the dangers of prediction, the right ways to develop skills, the pros and cons of fear and optimism, the difference between our experience and memory of events, the real components of happiness-each of these can be understood only by knowing how the two systems work together to shape our judgments and decisions.

Drawing on a lifetime's experimental experience, Kahneman reveals where we can and cannot trust our intuitions and how we can tap into the benefits of slow thinking. He offers practical and enlightening insights into how choices are made in both our professional and our personal lives-and how we can use different techniques to guard against the mental glitches that often get us into trouble. Thinking, Fast and Slow will transform the way you take decisions and experience the world.
LanguageEnglish
Release dateOct 25, 2011
ISBN9781846146701
Unavailable
Thinking, Fast and Slow
Author

Daniel Kahneman

Daniel Kahneman was the Eugene Higgins Professor of Psychology Emeritus at Princeton University and a former professor of public affairs at the Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs. He received the 2002 Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for his pioneering work with Amos Tversky on decision-making. He is the author of the international bestseller Thinking, Fast and Slow. He died in 2024.

More audiobooks from Daniel Kahneman

Related to Thinking, Fast and Slow

Related audiobooks

Business For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Thinking, Fast and Slow

Rating: 4.16300827269206 out of 5 stars
4/5

1,549 ratings103 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    This is a fascinating book. The author explains how the human mind works is a detailed, yet easily understood fashion. I have purchased copies for both my children and will re-read it again.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    This is one of the most detailed books, outside of textbooks, that I've read. It is organized very well. I leave it to you to look for a summary to get an idea of the contents. I listened to an audio version, but if you seriously want to absorb the material, I recommend a text version. I would like to give a better idea about the contents, but it really is too exhaustive. I can only say that it is well done and is not one of those repetitive self-help books. I heard many points with detailed studies showing me that most of us indeed have faults in the way we think. These faults are part of our being human and much of our "fast" thinking makes it possible for us to survive. I heard that basically just learning about these problem areas will not actually cause a change in how I make decisions for the most part. At the same time, I am encouraged to at least understand that the biases are there in our thinking so that I may be willing to entertain the thought that I might be wrong. I am maybe a bit more alert to the ways that my decision-making may even be manipulated.

    I was especially interested in the two selves: the remembering self and the experiencing self. This section alone was reason to read the book.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Anyone who has ever studied economics has probably marveled at the ridiculous assumption that economists make: That people weigh the outcome of their choices and make rational decisions. In the past few years, of course, a few books have shown how bad this assumption is. People just aren't that smart and they certainly aren't that rational. This book provides ample evidence of the types of errors we commonly make when thinking and weighing decisions. Backed by a plethora of research, the conclusions can help us avoid the pitfall of the fast-thinking part of our brain, which tends to simplify decisions and is prone to error, and engage the slow-thinking part, which has a better chance of doing the right thing. It took me a long time to read this book, because though it is engagingly written, it is still pretty dense. And it doesn't settle for just a few examples; it does its best to make its case as irrefutable as possible, and that means it weights in at almost 500 pages. But every page is worth your time. My only minor criticism is that their is too much avoidance of math; in a few instances having the probably of something actually expressed mathematically, and showing how that answer was arrived at, would have made things a bit clearer.Overall, however, a masterful effort. My home-schooled daughter read several economics texts this year, but I think this is the type of book to save for last, as a capstone. Highly, highly recommended. it will save your from some serious mistakes.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    This book is insightful and tought-provoking from beginning to end. A great read for anybody who wants to better understand humans, how they make decisions, and how they view the world.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Five stars from me for the amazing subtlety of its observations. Forget ego and id: this is a really convincing model of how we think, make decisions and mistakes, and what that might mean for us and even for public policy-- all based on the author's lifetime of work in psychology (and sometimes its intersections with economics). Though less accessible than other "popular" psychology books, TF&S has its own kind of pleasure-- the pleasures of recognition, like "Yes, I do over-emphasize small probabilities" or "Yes, I do substitute easier questions for more difficult ones," or more generally, "yes, that's me!"
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Daniel Kahneman is a psychology professor and the winner of a Nobel Prize in economics. In this book he delves into how the human mind works when we're evaluating situations, solving problems, and making decisions. In particular, he talks about two kinds of mental processing we employ. One, which he refers to as "System 1" (a phrase he emphasizes is simply a convenient label for a particular kind of thinking, not a physical thing that exists in your brain), works quickly, draws on associations between the problem before us and things we've seen before, simplifies complex problems to make them easier to handle, and produces results that just feel right. It's what we might like to call intuition. "System 2," on the other hand, proceeds slowly, logically, and analytically, for instance, when you're solving a complicated math problem. System 2 can be used to double-check on the intuitions provided by System 1, but it can also accept the conclusions System 1 feeds it and use those in its analysis. Or it can simply leave things to System 1 and never kick in at all.Both systems are useful, even crucial, in their proper domains. Without System 2, we'd never pass calculus, and without System 1, we'd be like the proverbial centipede who couldn't walk because he couldn't keep track of what all his legs were doing. But relying on System 1 can lead us astray in all kinds of ways. And Kahneman shows us many of the ways it does that, as well as exploring the difference between real people and the idealized economists' model of human beings as perfectly rational agents invariably acting in their own best self-interest.I thought most of this book was just really fantastic. I'd read a fair bit about this sort of topic before, and was a little afraid that it'd just hash over a lot of familiar ground for me, but, while I did get to be smug at having already developed the critical thinking skills not to fall for some of the trick questions designed to expose our irrationality, there was a lot here that I found really worthwhile and interesting, either because I was learning new things or because the already familiar concepts were just so wonderfully expressed.I will say that there was one multi-chapter section of the book I felt slightly less satisfied with. Mostly, that involved a lot of examination of how people say they would respond to an offered gamble or deal, and whether their responses are rational or not. There was definitely some good stuff in these chapters, but I found them much less interesting, and somewhat harder to get through than the others. In part, that's probably because the way economics types approach these kinds of problems always kind of irritates me. Even when they're trying really hard, they always seem to me to fail to appreciate how real people feel about real money, treating it as some kind of contextless shiny thing that's just abstractly nice to have. It tends to leave me wanting to grab them by the lapels and say things like, "Of course the possibility of losing money that you already have feels more significant than the possibility of winning the same amount. People fear losing money for the same reason they fear losing blood. You have a limited amount of it, can only replenish it so fast, and you need that stuff to live." I mean, come on, guys.Still, that may just be a personal quirk. Overall, it's an extremely valuable book, one that teaches some important, perhaps even utterly critical, lessons on the ways in which we can all be very, very wrong about things while being convinced we're completely, unquestionably right. Which is a perspective and a level of self-awareness that we desperately need more of in the world right now. I'd certainly like to force every politician to read it.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    A must-read for everyone who wants to make wise decisions!
    Especially, if decision-making is your job.
  • Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
    3/5
    This book is a good example of why you should not read too much about a book before reading it. The hype around this book was enormous. Everybody loved it. It was revolutionary. In the end, it's not a bad book, but I didn't think it was all that great, either. It is an interesting introduction to how we think, peppered with lots of examples, but it falls prey to what appears to be a lot of determinism, while acknowledging a smattering of environmental impact. In reality, I suspect much of what the author says is correct, but I did catch some things where he was incorrect or simplistic about something I do know something about, which always makes me suspicious of the things that are outside my usual field. Overall, I'm glad I read it, but I don't think I'd recommend it for others to read because I just wasn't that enthusiastic about his writing style (repetitive and somewhat dry) or the overall dynamic of the book.
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    I was prompted to read this for the sole reason that it gets referenced in so many other books. It lived up to the expectation. Kahneman was a pioneer in the space where human psychology confounds traditional economic theory. Now he's a venerable storyteller about that same space. The main point of the book is that the human mind uses two systems of thinking. One is fast, instinctual, and automatic. The other is slow, logical, and conceptual. Much of our behavior and later evaluation of it can be described by how those two systems are used under varying amounts of time pressure. The book is comprised of thirty-eight short chapters covering key concepts like regression to the mean, illusions of validity, and the importance of framing when evaluating options. I found his coverage of prospect theory especially complete and understandable compared to other descriptions I've encountered.
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    Opportunity cost is one of the key concepts of economics; doing this means you can't do that at the same time, for example. The early part of Thinking, Fast and Slow is about how the brain economizes on the time it spends making decisions. We could engage what Kahneman calls 'System 2', our reasoning framework, for each and every decision, but this would be hugely expensive in terms of opportunity costs. All that time we spent thinking we would not spending just getting on with things. So, in most cases, our brain allocates decision making to 'System 1', our more intuitive decision making system, our gut, which acts on a set of short cuts, heuristics. In this way, the brain has evolved to economize on thinking time.

    This can lead to what Kahneman calls 'mistakes' and the rational 'homo economicus' takes yet another kicking here. But his endorsement of 'nudge' policies, designed to move people towards the 'right' decisions, pre-supposes that the people doing the nudging know what these 'right' answers are. This knowledge, of course, has to be discovered.

    That said, the incorporation of prospect theory into microeconomics in place of expected utility theory looks to be a growing field of research in the future.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    A thoughtful and thought-provoking explanation of cognitive biases related to economics and decision making.
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    This is a very interesting look at how we humans think, and how we think we think! Do we always act in our best interests? Do we make rational economic decisions? Some of the ideas covered by Kahneman were also discussed in Michael Lewis's book, The Undoing Project. I am very glad I read Kahneman's book - much more depth.
  • Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
    3/5
    Reading Progress, Day One: My brain hurts.

    Reading Progress, Day Two: Mistake to read the Introduction that recommended reading the academic journal articles on which the book is premised. Now that I'm deep into Chapter 2, my System 1 and System 2 brain activities are finding a better balance and pace free of headaches.

    Reading Progress, Day Three: Many people are simply lazy thinkers. (And most of those lazy thinkers are obviously holding office in Washington, D. C.)

    Intermission: Yes, I've left off from my reading. You try to juggle course reading, conference submissions, and being both a teaching assistant and research assistant while attempting to earn rent money. I would bet your reading gets behind schedule, too. I'll have more to post later, but the fact of the matter is that lazy thinking works when you have a tight schedule.

    Reading completed: I must confess that I actually finished the book over a week ago after beginning the book well over three months ago. I am just now able to complete this review. (What's a few more days?) This is a tremendously beneficial book for self discovery of our biases. And, Kahneman does not pull punches when it comes to professionals (especially investment bankers). It all boils down to being suspicious of easy answers, paying attention to the base statistic, asking the question that no one is asking (which usually brings forth the opposite of the preferred outcome), watching for anchoring examples or thoughts that will influence your thinking, and being aware of biases - including professional bias due to ego.

    While a very clear, interesting, and informative book, I can't help but think that all of it could have been said in fewer than 512 pages. However, to be truthful, my favorite part of reading the book, which was for a graduate-level course, was to witness my professor praise the book and then proceed to break the principles of decision-making brought forward by Kahneman. The professor provided us with a continuous, live demonstration of egotistic bias and anchor setting.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Joy's review: Kahneman discusses how humans think. Good stuff, traps our minds lead us into, things we can control, things we can't. A fantastic book for anyone interested in knowing why we do the things we do. Sometimes too many details on the particular experiments, but a terrific book.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    The qualities of human nature described in Thinking, Fast and Slow are already known to all of us at some level. We are all taught in society to believe in the rational, thinking human being as distinct from his animal peers, yet as this book excellently details, there are plenty of ways in which our seemingly rational decisions can be bent and perverted by various forms of bias. Daniel Kahneman details these two seemingly incongruous facets of our nature as two 'distinct' halves: System 1 represents our autonomous, unthinking, reflex and subconscious reactions, whereas System 2 is that logical, calculating being we consider ourselves to be. Much of the relevant research covered in this volume was pioneered and conducted by Kahneman and his late colleague Amos Tversky, to whom this volume is dedicated.

    At root, the interplay between System 1 and System 2 rests upon the fact that we are naturally adapted to choose the path of least resistance, i.e. we make decisions which require the least amount of effort. Whilst this does not necessarily mean that we (or our System 2s) are not making the decisions, it does sometimes result in our System 2s acting merely as auditors of the information being passed on by System 1. If that information appears to fit the facts, it is taken at face value, unchanged and unedited. As a result, this 'quick thinking' leads to errors and biases of which we are almost entirely unaware.

    As a summary of decades of research, the book deals with a lot of extremely interesting aspects of these decision-making processes. Each of these is handled in turn and alone, although many of them are linked and could in some ways represent different impressions of the same phenomenon. For example, an issue known as 'anchoring' is investigated, a truly staggering anomaly in which a decision can be influenced by an entirely unrelated and random suggestion placed before us: Kahneman provides us with the example of a set of experienced judges whose sentencing decisions were seen to be tilted by the results of a dice roll.

    There is a lot of ground to summarise within these pages, and Kahneman does an excellent job of presenting some fairly mundane experimental data in a way in which it becomes clear to the layman, how insightful and potent the results truly are. The first half of the book in particular is an extremely fluid read, the experimental data plays second fiddle to clear evaluations of both experiments and their results. Whilst some aspects are dealt with purely theoretically, others are highlighted in terms of their effect on certain people in society, and Kahneman makes no bones about pointing out the absurd decisions of stock brokers, businessmen, or even his own psychology students. Another nice feature of the book is that many of the chapters start with a little test which readers themselves can do, becoming a part of the experiments, easily the best way to highlight precisely how 'un-rational' our minds can truly function.

    The overarching irony of this book is that it seems to want to prove one of the theories explored between its very covers, that of our 'experiencing' and 'remembering' selves. The evidence suggests that even if the vast majority of an experience was born with enjoyment, if the end was tainted, our memory of the positive experience will be overridden by the negative. Unfortunately, this book is guilty of the very same: it opens beautifully with some lucid and unhampered prose, plenty of example tests and real world extrapolations, occasional anecdotes and witty asides. Yet the latter half of the book feels like it was written by a different Kahneman or for a different reader; it is turgid, almost lethargic, sticky with academic language, no longer peppered with as many human insights, and devoid of example tests for the reader to take part in.

    Despite this impression of it being a book of two halves, it is nevertheless highly recommendable to anyone with even a passing interest in psychology or the human mind. One needn't take away any lessons from the book's insights, but it would still be nice to think that by giving this book five stars, I'm successfully overcoming the biassed suggestions of System 1 and my 'remembering self', and basing my judgement on the rational observations of System 2 and my 'experiencing self'. Or perhaps I'm being swayed by some anchoring I'm still unaware of...
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Really loved reading this book. It was recommended by one of my friends several years ago.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    This book is an enduring masterpiece. I'm afraid not a few people would miss it.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Amazing book, would recommend reading it to anyone. 5/5
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    Hey guys, where can I find pdf format of this book, please?
  • Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
    3/5
    ¿Que le gusto y que no acerca de
    este libro?
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    OK, I won't lie to you. Caveats first. I was an English major and I love science. Math, not so much. A couple of the chapters near the end of the book had my eyes crossing, but I did not give up and neither should you. This is a fascinating book. An important book. It is a perfect companion to all the other things I have read on the workings of the human brain. It has important implications for everyday decision making as well as public policy. Read it.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Highlights from this book should be required reading in high school.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    A model for how we think. Either fast and lose or slow with the possibility of more correct decisions.
    Thinking fast we risk jumping to conclusions, not see the broad picture, have planning fallacies, framing based decisions.
    Thinking slow: we can step back and compare things. Look out side the box. Look at the problem from multiple framings.

    I think this is a book that I will read again in a year or two. This is my second reading.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    An amazing intro to a field I knew nothing about. Definitely deserves many more re-reads. Would I benefit from it? doubt it. Nonetheless an extremely enjoyable book.

    PS: Always be cautious of your own mind.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Among other things, scientific validation of the Hindu concept of maya. Significant implications for creativity and understanding the nature of religious experience.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    I first encountered the work of Daniel Kahneman and his collaborator Amos Tversky when I was in graduate school. A student of artificial intelligence, I was keenly interested in the question of how to design systems that can behave ?rationally? despite their computational limits. I was thinking about computer systems, but of course human beings are also systems that have limits on the amount of ?computation??or at least thinking?that they can do. The adage of economists that rational behavior consists in doing the actions that do the most to further one?s goals given one?s beliefs simply didn?t seem to make a lot of sense when considered from a computational perspective: weighing one?s options in light of one?s goals and beliefs takes time, and if you try to weigh all your options, the world will change before you?ve finished. As various people have said, human beings are not ?frictionless deliberators.?Enter Kahneman and Tversky, whose work showed that people deviate in systematic ways from the standard model of rational thinking. The key insight is that the deviations are systematic?and they?re systematic in ways that accord with having finite reasoning capabilities. It?s not that people are irrational?Kahneman bristles at that description of his results. Rather it?s that the model of rational thinking developed by the economists may be fine as a normative model, but can?t work as a descriptive one.Kahneman and Tversky collaborated on psychological studies of reasoning for more than a decade, writing hugely influential papers, including their 1974 Science article ?Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases,? which is amongst the most highly cited paper in economics, and which reproduced in full in ?Thinking Fast and Slow.? Tversky died in 1996 at the age of 59, but Kahneman went on to win the Nobel Prize in Economics for their joint work in 2002. Indeed, ?Thinking Fast and Slow? is a joy to read not only for the science it contains, but also, secondarily, for the touching accounts he provides of his long collaboration with Tversky.This is Kahneman?s magnum opus: an overarching review of 50 years of research that he conducted, first with Tversky, and subsequently with other leading social scientists. It?s remarkably accessible, even when he?s describing somewhat arcane points of psychology. Amongst the many cognitive biases he describes are these:?Seemingly little things that make it easier to process information?the size or darkness of the font in text, for example?have a powerful effect on the likelihood that you will believe or approve of the information.?We readily adopt a principle of WYSIATI?what you see is all there is. We neglect the possibility that our conclusions may be biased by having only incomplete information.?We tend to apply a halo effect in assessing other people?s character or capabilities: we make specific assessments based on overall impression of them, and the errors that this induces are compounded by WYSIATI.?When we?re trying to answer a challenging question, we often substitute an easier one, without even realizing it.?Our numeric judgments are biases by ?anchoring effects? in which we are swayed by sometimes irrelevant numbers that we encounter during our reasoning process.?We often assess the quality of an experience by what happens at the end of it.These are just six of the dozens of biases that Kahneman describes. For each bias, he presents the sometimes astonishing psychological studies that support it. For example, the last bias was uncovered in experiment with a group of patients who underwent colonoscopies in the early 1990s, when anesthesia was not well-administered for these procedures. One group of patients had a few extra minutes added to the procedure at the end, during which they experienced a relatively reduced level of pain. The patients in that group felt that the experience was overall less unpleasant, even though they?d experienced all the pain of the other group plus some more!There?s an overarching coherence to Kahenman?s work: he explains human decision-making and the cognitive biases it includes, in terms of two systems: a quick-and-dirty Malcolm-Gladwell-like System 1, which, when needed, provides information and tentative conclusions to a more effortful, deliberative System 2. However, while you might be tempted to think that the errors produced by the types of cognitive biases listed above are solely the result of System 1, that would be incorrect. In fact, the connection between ?accurate? reasoning and two systems is more complex, and even when humans rely on System 2, they are still not able to behave in the ?fully rational? ways that would be specified by classical economics. It takes some careful reading of Kahneman?s book to sort this out, but on careful consideration one realizes that even with System 2 the economist?s rationality can?t be fully obtained. How could it, by creatures with finite brains?
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    I first encountered the work of Daniel Kahneman and his collaborator Amos Tversky when I was in graduate school. A student of artificial intelligence, I was keenly interested in the question of how to design systems that can behave “rationally” despite their computational limits. I was thinking about computer systems, but of course human beings are also systems that have limits on the amount of “computation”—or at least thinking—that they can do. The adage of economists that rational behavior consists in doing the actions that do the most to further one’s goals given one’s beliefs simply didn’t seem to make a lot of sense when considered from a computational perspective: weighing one’s options in light of one’s goals and beliefs takes time, and if you try to weigh all your options, the world will change before you’ve finished. As various people have said, human beings are not “frictionless deliberators.”Enter Kahneman and Tversky, whose work showed that people deviate in systematic ways from the standard model of rational thinking. The key insight is that the deviations are systematic—and they’re systematic in ways that accord with having finite reasoning capabilities. It’s not that people are irrational—Kahneman bristles at that description of his results. Rather it’s that the model of rational thinking developed by the economists may be fine as a normative model, but can’t work as a descriptive one.Kahneman and Tversky collaborated on psychological studies of reasoning for more than a decade, writing hugely influential papers, including their 1974 Science article “Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases,” which is amongst the most highly cited paper in economics, and which reproduced in full in “Thinking Fast and Slow.” Tversky died in 1996 at the age of 59, but Kahneman went on to win the Nobel Prize in Economics for their joint work in 2002. Indeed, “Thinking Fast and Slow” is a joy to read not only for the science it contains, but also, secondarily, for the touching accounts he provides of his long collaboration with Tversky.This is Kahneman’s magnum opus: an overarching review of 50 years of research that he conducted, first with Tversky, and subsequently with other leading social scientists. It’s remarkably accessible, even when he’s describing somewhat arcane points of psychology. Amongst the many cognitive biases he describes are these:•Seemingly little things that make it easier to process information—the size or darkness of the font in text, for example—have a powerful effect on the likelihood that you will believe or approve of the information.•We readily adopt a principle of WYSIATI—what you see is all there is. We neglect the possibility that our conclusions may be biased by having only incomplete information.•We tend to apply a halo effect in assessing other people’s character or capabilities: we make specific assessments based on overall impression of them, and the errors that this induces are compounded by WYSIATI.•When we’re trying to answer a challenging question, we often substitute an easier one, without even realizing it.•Our numeric judgments are biases by “anchoring effects” in which we are swayed by sometimes irrelevant numbers that we encounter during our reasoning process.•We often assess the quality of an experience by what happens at the end of it.These are just six of the dozens of biases that Kahneman describes. For each bias, he presents the sometimes astonishing psychological studies that support it. For example, the last bias was uncovered in experiment with a group of patients who underwent colonoscopies in the early 1990s, when anesthesia was not well-administered for these procedures. One group of patients had a few extra minutes added to the procedure at the end, during which they experienced a relatively reduced level of pain. The patients in that group felt that the experience was overall less unpleasant, even though they’d experienced all the pain of the other group plus some more!There’s an overarching coherence to Kahenman’s work: he explains human decision-making and the cognitive biases it includes, in terms of two systems: a quick-and-dirty Malcolm-Gladwell-like System 1, which, when needed, provides information and tentative conclusions to a more effortful, deliberative System 2. However, while you might be tempted to think that the errors produced by the types of cognitive biases listed above are solely the result of System 1, that would be incorrect. In fact, the connection between “accurate” reasoning and two systems is more complex, and even when humans rely on System 2, they are still not able to behave in the “fully rational” ways that would be specified by classical economics. It takes some careful reading of Kahneman’s book to sort this out, but on careful consideration one realizes that even with System 2 the economist’s rationality can’t be fully obtained. How could it, by creatures with finite brains?
  • Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
    4/5
    This book gives a comprehensive knowledge regarding how one makes a decision under different circumstances and what are the relevant factors that needs to be considered. Downside is that the author refers to various figures and tables frequently, however, this audiobook doesn't come with any attached pdf file.
  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    Needs PDF attachment. Great book with a lot of insightful, useful analysis on the way we think.

    1 person found this helpful

  • Rating: 5 out of 5 stars
    5/5
    I really loved this book. Kahneman provides a brief but extensive introduction to concepts in the psychology of decision making - and how decision making can go wrong.He discusses various theories and complements them with ample material from research - as well as from his own experience.The book is an engaging and fun read, often surprising and entertaining, without becoming superficial.Though it is of course not an extensive treatment of the subject, it is definitely a great introduction, and it gives plenty of notes and references for further exploration of the topic.