Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It
Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It
Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It
Ebook608 pages7 hours

Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

In a provocative assessment of American poverty and policy from 1950 to the present, Frank Stricker examines an era that has seen serious discussion about the causes of poverty and unemployment. Analyzing the War on Poverty, theories of the culture of poverty and the underclass, the effects of Reaganomics, and the 1996 welfare reform, Stricker demonstrates that most antipoverty approaches are futile without the presence (or creation) of good jobs. Stricker notes that since the 1970s, U.S. poverty levels have remained at or above 11%, despite training programs and periods of economic growth. The creation of jobs has continued to lag behind the need for them.

Stricker argues that a serious public debate is needed about the job situation; social programs must be redesigned, a national health care program must be developed, and economic inequality must be addressed. He urges all sides to be honest--if we don't want to eliminate poverty, then we should say so. But if we do want to reduce poverty significantly, he says, we must expand decent jobs and government income programs, redirecting national resources away from the rich and toward those with low incomes. Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It is sure to prompt much-needed debate on how to move forward.

LanguageEnglish
Release dateFeb 1, 2011
ISBN9780807882290
Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It
Author

Frank Stricker

Frank Stricker is professor of history at California State University, Dominguez Hills.

Related to Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It

Related ebooks

Public Policy For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    Why America Lost the War on Poverty--And How to Win It - Frank Stricker

    Why America Lost the War on Poverty—And How to Win It

    Why America Lost the War on Poverty–And How to Win It

    FRANK STRICKER

    THE UNIVERSITY OF NORTH CAROLINA PRESS

    Chapel Hill

    © 2007 The University of North Carolina Press

    All rights reserved

    Manufactured in the United States of America

    Designed by Jacquline Johnson

    Set in Bembo by Keystone Typesetting

    The publication of this book was supported by a generous grant from the Division of Academic Affairs, California State University, Dominguez Hills.

    An earlier version of chapter 7 appeared as Why American Poverty Rates Stopped Falling in the 70s, and Why a Better Story Was Not Told about It, Journal of Poverty 4, no. 4 (2000): 1 –21;an earlier version of chapter 10 appeared as Staying Poor in the Clinton Boom: Welfare Reform and the Nearby Labor Force, Journalof Poverty 7, nos. 1–2 (2003): 23–49, and in Keith M. Kilty and Elizabeth A. Segal, eds., Rediscoveringthe Other America: The Continuing Crisis ofPoverty and Inequality in the United States (New York: Haworth Press, 2003).

    The paper in this book meets the guidelines for permanence and durability of the Committee on Production Guidelines for Book Longevity of the Council on Library Resources.

    Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication

    Data

    Stricker, Frank.

    Why America lost the war on poverty—and how

    to win it / Frank Stricker.

    p. cm.

    Includes bibliographical references and index.

    ISBN 978-0-8078-3111-3 (cloth: alk. paper)

    ISBN 978-0-8078-5804-2 (pbk.: alk. paper)

    1. Poverty—United States—History—20th

    century. 2. Poor—United States—History—20th

    century. I. Title.

    HC110.P6S78 2007

    362.5′560973—dc22 2007012426

    cloth 11 10 09 08 07 5 4 3 2 1

    paper 11 10 09 08 07 5 4 3 2 1

    To my wife,

    DEBORAH SCHOPP,

    and to all good people

    who fight for a real

    government war

    on poverty

    CONTENTS

    Preface

    Introduction

    PART ONE THE GOLDEN AGE OF LAISSEZ-FAIRE?: THE 50S

    ONE The 1950s: Limited Government, Limited Affluence

    PART TWO WARS ON POVERTY: THE 60S

    TWO Planning the War on Poverty: Fixing the Poor or Fixing the Economy?

    THREE Evaluating the War on Poverty: the Conservatism of Liberalism

    FOUR Moynihan, the Dissenters, and the Racialization of Poverty: a Liberal Turning Point that did Not Turn

    FIVE Statistics and Theory of Unemployment and Poverty: Lessons From the 60s and the Postwar Era

    PART THREE TOWARD A WAR ON THE POOR: THE 70S AND 80S

    SIX The Politics of Poverty and Welfare in the 70s: From Nixon to Carter

    SEVEN Too Much Work Ethic: One Reason Poverty Rates Stopped Falling in the 70s, and the Stories that Were Told about it

    EIGHT Cutting Poverty or Cutting Welfare: Conservatives Attack Liberalism

    NINE Reagan, Reaganomics, and the American Poor, 1980–1992

    PART FOUR THE POOR YOU WILL ALWAYS HAVE WITH YOU—IF YOU DON’T DO THE RIGHT THING: 1993–PRESENT

    TEN Staying Poor in the Clinton Boom: Welfare Reform, the Nearby Labor Force, and the Limits of the Work Ethic

    ELEVEN Bush and beyond: on solving and not solving poverty

    APPENDIX1 Unemployment, Poverty, Earnings, and Household Structure

    FIGURE A.1. Annual Official Civilian Unemployment Rate and Author’s Estimate of Real Rate, 1959–2005 245

    FIGURE A.2. U.S. Poverty Rates, 1950–2004 246

    FIGURE A.3. Real Weekly Earnings of Production and Nonsupervisory Workers in the Private Sector, 1964–2005 246

    FIGURE A.4. Percentage of Poor by Household Type, 1959, 1979, 1998 247

    APPENDIX2 Groups Often Left Out of Antipoverty Discussions in the 60s and Today

    Notes

    Bibliographical Essay

    Index

    ILLUSTRATIONS, FIGURES, AND TABLES

    ILLUSTRATIONS

    Michael Harrington 44

    If you had any initiative, you’d go out and inherit a department store52

    Typing class at Woman’s Job Corps Center 64

    School dropouts at a Maryland Job Corps Center 66

    They’ve been going together for quite a while111

    Johnnie Tillmon addressing a Mother’s Day March on Washington 119

    Mollie Orshansky 154

    Boiler plant in Youngstown, Ohio 196

    Bethlehem Steel 215

    Union members employed at the Fairmont Hotel in San Francisco 242

    FIGURES

    1.1 Poor Families by Type of Head of Household, 1959 12

    1.2 National and Black Unemployment Rates, 1948–1965 16

    7.1 U.S. Poverty Rates, 1950–1980 142

    7.2 Employment Rates of Black and White Male Teens, 1960–1993 150

    10.1 Real Average Hourly Earnings of Production and Non-supervisory Private Nonagricultural Workers, 1961–2001 212

    TABLES

    1.1 Poor and Nearly Poor Families in 1960 21

    1.2 Percentage of Female-Headed Families by Race 23

    3.1 Work Experience of Poor Family Heads in 1963 68

    4.1 Percentage of Female-Headed Families in Selected Urban Racial/Income Groups, 1960 90

    5.1 Ghetto Subemployment in 1966 108

    5.2 Real Unemployment, 1971: Some Who Should Have Been Added to Official Estimates of the Unemployed 110

    7.1 Percentage of Workers Earning at or below Poverty Wages, 1973–1979 147

    10.1 Relative Poverty Rates before and after Government Programs, 1991 227

    PREFACE

    I was not poor when I grew up in the 50s, but I know that my family felt cramped. We had five people in a small house with two bedrooms. My father, a house painter, worked hard and usually steadily, but he probably did not charge his customers enough. The family never had a vacation together. I remember my mother using a wooden egg to darn a patch where we had holes in our socks.

    I have rarely been unemployed. For most of my high school and college years I worked in the university library or as my father’s assistant. I recall that at one point in the early 1960s my dad was paying me $5 an hour; that was the equivalent of more than $30 today. My father was too generous as an employer, as he was too generous to his customers. But the high pay for an apprentice house painter seems appropriate to that better time for American workers.

    Although I suffered only one year of real unemployment in my life, I had more than a decade of worries about keeping the academic position I accepted at California State, Dominguez Hills, in the fall of 1972. California’s finances were on a three-decade seesaw, and faculty and staff often worried that they would be laid off. Most weren’t, but the dark cloud of unemployment stayed with me for a long time. And it stayed over the California State Universities, although its shape has changed; now Cal State makes extensive use of underemployed and underpaid part-time professors.

    Poverty and living standards have been an interest for many years. In the 70s and 80s I participated in meat boycotts, worked with unions, studied the latest inflation and unemployment crises, and learned about Marxism. I have never taken an economics course, and perhaps it shows. But I learned a lot about economics and history from friends in the New American Movement and in the Westcoast Association of Marxist Historians.

    By the time I decided to write this book, I had been teaching and writing about poverty, incomes, and unemployment for two decades. Although I am undeniably comfortable today, I have not forgotten where I came from or that life is an economic struggle for most people, even in this, the richest nation in the history of the world. I hope this book finds many different audiences, but above all, I want it to be of political use to working-class students like those I teach.

    So many people helped along the way. First are my students at California State University, Dominguez Hills. They read chapters and offered suggestions, especially on how to make the book more reader-friendly. Years after taking my courses, they remembered I was writing a book and asked how it was coming. It was nice that they wanted to know when they could buy a copy.

    Next are colleagues at California State University, Dominguez Hills. Lois Feuer, Don Lewis, Linda Pomerantz, John Auld, Myrna Donahoe, and David Churchman are among those who read chapters and offered valuable suggestions. Also at Dominguez Hills, colleagues on awards committees were sometimes generous. Several administrators offered financial and moral support. Deans Richard Palmer and Selase Williams encouraged me, as did department and program chairs. Don Castro came up with a grant that gave me a boost; Allen Mori and Laura Robles helped support this book. Sabbaticals and partial-pay leaves were extremely important. Marilyn Brady, Jean Butler, and Ineki Fike, all wonderful staff people, helped out in direct and indirect ways. The librarians at my university provided efficient support, perhaps most of all those in the Interlibrary Loan Department, led by Faye Phinsee-Clack. Finally, I was blessed with exceptional research assistants. These students were smart and eager; they never said no when I asked them to find something. I hope I have not forgotten anyone: Jane Lexow, Liz Tamoush, Linda Jackson, Glenn Brit-ton, Dan Kenney, Kathryn Katsenis, and Daniel Gardner.

    Charles Grench, American history editor at the University of North Carolina Press, his assistant Katy V. O’Brien, associate managing editor Paula Wald, and copy editor Grace Carino helped me get through a long journey to final publication. The outside reviewers for the University of North Carolina Press, Melvyn Dubofsky and Edward Berkowitz, were generous critics and made me read more widely. Historian and old friend Doug Monroy read chapters early on. Pat Palmieri was supportive all the way, and she encouraged me to link up with Charles Grench. Two economists helped out. Tom Larson gave valuable criticism, especially of chapters 4 and 5, and Jim Devine tried to answer my queries. Gordon Fisher helped me understand poverty lines and adequate budgets. Joan Williams applied a fine-tooth comb to several sections. Sociologist Ellen Reese commented especially on chapter 8. The staff of the Journal of Poverty, led by Keith Kilty, gave me pointed criticisms on several occasions. So did participants at the annual conventions of the Southwest Labor Studies Association, notably the late Tim Sampson. Librarians at the John F. Kennedy Library sent copies of documents relating to the War on Poverty. Many people, including Martha Bishop in Ohio and Larry DeWitt at the Social Security Administration in Washington, helped me acquire illustrations. Above all, members of the Los Angeles Social History Study Group read every chapter at least once and patiently offered trenchant criticisms. I learned much from the critical process of the group. It has endured for a quarter of a century, and its recent membership included Hal Barron, Carla Bittel, the late Clark Davis, Bill Deverell, Phil Ethington, Nancy Fitch, John Laslett, Nelson Lichtenstein, Margot McBane, Jan Reiff, Seth Rockman, Troy Rondinone, Steve Ross, Diana Selig, Bob Slayton, Jessica Wang, Tom Zakim, and Leila Zenderland.

    Antipoverty workers who spoke to my classes shaped the way I thought about the book. Nancy Berlin, Bob Erlenbusch, Alton Donatto, Valerie Grab, and Paul Freese all inspired me with their tenacity, deep knowledge of people, and moral strength. Finally, my family helped me complete this work. Although they might not understand some of it and they would disagree with many of its conclusions, my parents, now deceased, would be proud of this book. My brothers and their partners, Bert and Margot and Jim and Debby, will also disagree with much, but they have been supportive of my career. My mother-in-law, Virginia Bragg, helped out in ways that she may not even know. My son, Vonn Schopp, helped with technical support and much else. My daughter, Alexis Schopp, did research and often helped me become a little less computer-illiterate. Finally, my wife, Deborah Schopp, read many chapters and offered loving support every step of the way. She is a patient, steadying force in my life.

    INTRODUCTION

    Historical Overview

    Two hundred years ago, poverty was a pressing issue in the United States. Influenced by Enlightenment rationalism, Protestant evangelicalism, and American self-confidence, reformers believed that they could cure poverty. In those years, as in other times, the causes of poverty were debated, but most people chose one of two big explanations. The first blamed the poor; laziness or foolishness caused them to be impoverished. The second emphasized political and economic structures that failed to provide enough jobs and that dealt too much income to the rich and too little to the majority.¹

    Today we are vastly richer than we were in the early 1800s, and our governments operate dozens of programs that help the poor. But if much has changed, much remains the same. In every year of the past fifty, at least 11% and often much more of the U.S. population has been poor. (This is according to official U.S. poverty lines, which meant that in 2004 a family of four with more than $19,157 a year was not poor.)² The 37 million officially poor in 2004 did not include millions of Americans in a state of near poverty, above the miserably low government poverty lines but below a decent standard of living.

    This book is about the past half century of our national debate about poverty. In the 1950s we were not much concerned about the poor. Anticommunism stifled critical economic thinking, and our leaders had faith in the economic growth machine. But when growth faltered in the late 50s, a serious discussion began about the causes of poverty and unemployment. Conservatives had their views, too, but much debate occurred among liberals and liberal scholars. How much poverty and unemployment was caused by the fact that the economy was not growing fast enough? How much was due to specific factors such as racism, regional decline, automation, and people’s lack of schooling and skills?

    In the late 50s and early 60s, liberals and leftists prepared the way for the War on Poverty, but they sometimes misled the public by emphasizing the defective mentality of the poor. In The Affluent Society (1958) liberal economist John Kenneth Galbraith claimed that the poor were just a handful of people outside the economic mainstream. Socialist writer Michael Harrington seemed at times to agree. Elsewhere Harrington pushed for economic growth and urged government to create jobs, but in his most famous book, The Other America (1962),he prepared the ground for a War on Poverty that focused on poor people’s defects.

    The 1960s were the last period of triumphant liberalism in our history. President Lyndon Johnson and his economists adopted a three-part recipe for prosperity: tax cuts to spur economic growth, the War on Poverty to rehabilitate and train the damaged poor for the jobs that growth would generate, and programs like Medicare, Medicaid, and food stamps to fix the problems that remained. We shall see whether this liberal project succeeded or whether, as conservatives maintained, it caused laziness and poverty.

    At points in the 60s and 70s, some liberal intellectuals and politicians inched toward a more radical position: growth would never eliminate unemployment and job-related poverty. Government would have to create jobs directly. A small group led by Harrington and Daniel Patrick Moynihan had urged this approach in planning the War on Poverty, but to no avail. Moynihan reportedly suggested that the U.S. Postal Service bring back two mail deliveries a day, for that would create 50,000 good jobs. The urban riots of mostly poor people in the late 60s also put job creation on the agenda. Secretary of Labor Wil-lard Wirtz’s survey of real inner-city unemployment showed appalling levels of misery. These seedlings might have refocused poverty policy toward direct job creation.

    Although President Richard Nixon eliminated components of the War on Poverty, tentative steps were taken toward a new antipoverty policy in the early 1970s. Nixon’s plan for a guaranteed income failed in Congress, but presidents and Congresses approved large hikes in Social Security benefits, an Earned Income Tax Credit for working poor families, and a program of government jobs for the poor and the unemployed.

    Despite these victories for government antipoverty ventures, the political balance was shifting against liberalism in the 70s. Backlash to radical movements of the 60s played a role, but so also did soaring inflation and rising unemployment. Conservative scholars such as Martin Anderson argued that government social programs discouraged hard work and entrepreneurship. As the decade came to a close, there was still strong backing for Social Security, but popular support for programs serving the poor wavered. Meanwhile, business mobilized against government regulations and social programs, the conservative movement was growing in sophistication, and liberals seemed confused.

    By the mid-80s, with Ronald Reagan in the White House and author Charles Murray doing the talk show circuit, conservatives began to shape public debate on poverty, welfare, and unemployment. In effect, they encouraged white workers to turn against the average poor person of color. But why didn’t labor and liberals make political hay out of global changes, deindustrial-ization, and recessions, which clearly did not stem from people’s laziness or overly generous welfare programs? Perhaps liberals and leftists had not, in the 60s and early 70s, significantly modified popular beliefs about individual blame for being poor—or even their own beliefs. Had the liberals won the legislative battles but lost the intellectual war? Or perhaps liberalism’s penchant for government action was, as conservatives maintained, fundamentally flawed.

    In the 80s and 90s, almost no one talked about direct government job creation to solve unemployment and poverty. That seedling of the 60s and 70s had wilted. Liberals as well as conservatives did little to stop the influx of cheap foreign imports. In the Clinton boom of the 90s almost no one spoiled the party by asking whether positive reports on welfare reform, poverty, and unemployment ignored a lot of reality. There was more talk about the harmful effects of welfare than about the harmful effects of unemployment.

    In the first years of the new millennium, the great American job machine again faltered. Between the start of recession in March 2001 and the spring of 2005, the private sector showed essentially no net job increase. Not only did the total increase in jobs trail the average of other postwar recoveries, but all the net gain was in government jobs—a curious outcome for an administration that claimed to be conservative.³ Meanwhile, poverty began inching up again, but even in the presidential campaign of 2004, there was not much debate about poverty or jobs. And little was said about the fact that the United States had the highest poverty rate of all the rich democracies.

    Assumptions and Intentions

    This book is intended primarily for concerned citizens and upper-level college students. It describes the political, economic, and intellectual history of poverty and unemployment over five decades. But it is more than a descriptive history. It explains why things turned out the way they did. And it suggests that other roads might have been taken.

    Staying out of poverty is only in part a matter of individual effort; it is also and more so about institutions and structures that allow individual aspirations to bloom or die. Most of this book assumes that, all other things being equal, the level of individual effort has not changed much in fifty years. But structures and institutions have, and so most of what follows is about big causes.

    I believe that several approaches are necessary to solve poverty, but I often focus on jobs because I believe that many antipoverty approaches are futile without good jobs and because I believe it is necessary to confront the conservative command to the poor—"Get a Job!"—with reality. I show in several chapters that unemployment was higher than we were told and that we often had a labor glut. I believe that whenever full employment seems within reach, the authorities curb economic growth in order to combat wage and price inflation. That is, the growth remedy for unemployment and poverty is never allowed to work long enough to complete the task that its defenders claim for it. So there is always a job shortage, and as long as there is a job shortage, there will be poverty among people who want to work.

    I have learned a great deal from many scholars and activists, but my model of unemployment and job-related poverty comes mostly from reading Marxists and liberal writers and from studying the course of history since the mid-nineteenth century. The historical record demonstrates that a substantial amount of unemployment is normal for capitalism; capitalists don’t want a thirties-style depression, but they do want a fair amount of unemployment in order to control workers and suppress wages. If this is true, then the years of relatively low unemployment—for example, in the early 50s and the late 90s—are the exception; except during big wars, unemployment never stays low for very long. And in recent decades, when faced with stiff competition from abroad, American businesses have traveled the globe in order to enlarge the available labor force. In effect, capitalists take advantage of the worldwide labor surplus, that is, of high unemployment around the globe.

    As long as the cozy relationship between government and capital continues, job-related poverty is not likely to be solved. With a few tweaks here and there, Social Security can eliminate poverty for people who have finished working; it has just about done so already. But for those who need and want to work for pay, poverty rates are about where they were in the 1970s.

    It seems to me that our leaders must be forced to promote enough economic growth to bring a long period of full employment, or take alternative steps to create jobs and raise wages. While each approach would require a broad political movement to compel action, the latter, direct approach may be easier. As to the first, I am convinced that when faced with a choice—and without counteracting pressures—our economic rulers at the Federal Reserve and in the White House will always choose less inflation over less unemployment and they will always favor capital over average Americans with subsidies and tax cuts. Barring government policies to promote a long economic boom that creates millions of permanent high-wage jobs, our leaders should admit that our government-coddled private markets cannot erase poverty. Then, if the fit of honesty continues, they can do either of two things. One is to confess to the public that they think it is best that we live permanently with 20% of the population poor and nearly poor. The other is to work with movements that support redistribution of income away from the very rich and toward the poor, direct government job creation, and government efforts to protect unionization and require higher pay.

    Much more than job creation must be done to wipe out poverty. We can improve the schools and do better at retooling people’s skills. But while more training and better schools are essential, they won’t help the poor if the jobs aren’t there.

    Of course, much poverty is not job-related. As another part of any anti-poverty program, we must redesign rather than cut social programs. For example, some people cannot escape poverty by finding traditional jobs. Caretakers—parents caring for their children, children caring for aging parents, all who nurse sick friends and neighbors—deserve income.

    And we need a national health program; on health care we spend more per capita, more in total, and more on administration than any other nation on earth, but we don’t have the healthiest people, and millions are without secure access to medical care. Rising health insurance costs inhibit employers from hiring more workers, and they may make domestic businesses less competitive with foreign businesses in which health insurance costs are controlled and more universally shared. Did liberals err in the 60s by not trying for national health insurance to cover all?

    To state the issue more broadly, we need less economic inequality and a frank recognition that a tiny class of rich people lives off the insecurities of a large class we might call the economic majority. The reader can judge whether liberals were politically shrewd or sadly mistaken in deemphasizing class and not making economic equality a bigger issue in the 60s. It seemed then that economic growth would create enough income to help the poor without having to take from the rich. But over the 80s and 90s, it became clear in the economic statistics that the richest took so much new income that there wasn’t much left for the rest. Wages for most workers stagnated while executive pay soared. That meant more poverty.

    At times liberals acted as though solving poverty was not a political issue and not, in some broad sense, a class issue. But it is both. It was not just impersonal forces that allotted more income to the rich and less to the middle and the bottom. Since the early 70s the rich and the wannabes have organized with great energy and ruthlessness to win many political battles. They are still winning them in the early 2000s. That has meant more inequality and more poverty. To solve poverty, some people are going to have to be made to give up some of their riches. More good jobs and more income for the poor cannot be created out of thin air.

    Conservatives acted as though classes were nonexistent or not important, and liberals tried to run around the issue, arguing that everyone would gain from growth and good social programs. But if growth fails to create enough jobs or cure much poverty, what then? This situation became more likely in the 80s and 90s, when there were many years of high unemployment and corporate policy became leaner and meaner. In the 50s and 60s, it was possible to believe that corporate success would lift everyone; people at the top took less than they do now, and those at the bottom did better. But with intense foreign competition and rampant capital flight, life became more tenuous even for those who considered themselves middle class. Although many stayed middle income, many suffered volatile income swings. They were like the Jacobson family, which earned $60,000 in one year but, because of health crises and bad job markets, was forced the next year to beg for charity in order to meet house payments. Or the Ryans, who earned at least $100,000 a year in the late 80s but later were rocked by corporate collapses and medical catastrophes and had to declare bankruptcy twice. Or like millions of working poor and not poor Americans, whose incomes gyrate much more wildly than they did thirty years ago.

    Whether American politics and culture will change enough to confront increasing economic insecurity is up for grabs. In 2005 there was a disconnection between economic reality and public debate. In part this was the effect of living in a very rich country where there is a lot of income, a lot of material goods, and a lot of debt. But it also involved the mental frameworks that shape the way we think about class and power. Will our tradition of individualism and our desire to belong to the middle class inhibit the development of a Coalition of the Economic Majority against the top tenth that grows richer day by day? Will people find enough economic compensation from two-earner families and low-priced imports, enough warmth in religion, and enough escape in entertainment that they can ignore not only other people’s poverty and joblessness but the hugely unequal distribution of incomes and their own shaky situation? In 2025 will we still be wondering why nothing is being done about the health insurance crisis and our 40 million poor people?

    part one

    The Golden Age of Laissez-Faire?: The 50s

    chapter one

    THE 1950S

    Limited Government, Limited Affluence

    For many Americans the decade of the 1950s has an agreeable image. As people stumbled through the turmoil of later years, they remembered the era of Dwight Eisenhower and Lucille Ball as a time of prosperity and moral calm. Two books published in 1986 reflected this warm popular assessment: William O’Neill’s American High: The Years of Confidence, 1945–1960 and J. Ronald Oakley’s God’s Country: America in the 50s.

    Of course, there were negative reviews; they included claims that anticom-munism and consumerism quashed critical thinking and that economic advances were limited. Lawrence Wittner wrote of a blackout of critical opinion, and Douglas Miller and Marion Nowak assailed the decade’s celebration of people’s capitalism, the myth of a fair and democratic economy. These authors pointed out that millions of Americans remained poor and that economic power was still exercised by a tiny group of corporate leaders.¹

    My chapter is in the second school. It challenges our cheery image of the 50s by examining poverty and how Americans defined poverty. It judges whether the economy of the 50s cured poverty, and whether it did so without significant government assistance. Were the 50s proof that individual willpower and laissez-faire policies were sufficient antipoverty programs, as conservatives later claimed? We will see that growth was strong and that it cured much poverty, especially in the early 50s, but also that government’s role was vital in both promoting economic growth and lifting the destitute. Success against poverty evaporated in the late 50s when the president refused to spend.²

    Linked to the issue of what government should do, a discussion began whose outcome would profoundly influence antipoverty policy. The discussion involved a big question. Were the high unemployment and persistent poverty of the late 50s due to discrete problems of specific groups (such as racism) or to large defects in the economy? Were people poor because of skill deficits and dysfunctional lower-class cultures or because they were simply the most distressed section of a large working class that suffered from deeply based income inequalities and a long-term labor glut? In short, was poverty caused by defective individuals and subcultures or by capitalism?

    The 50s as Economic Utopia

    The economy of the 50s seemed robust. Real (that is, after eliminating the effects of price changes) gross domestic product (all the goods and services produced in the United States) was 41% larger in 1960 than in 1950. Because the average tax bite did not rise much and because income inequality did not worsen, after-tax real income for the average family grew by an amazing 41%.³

    The 50s were especially good for male workers, in part because the baby bust of the 20s and 30s meant less competition for good jobs. The male work force grew by less than 1% a year. At the same time, and contradicting widely held views that women belonged at home, the female labor force grew by almost 25%. While wives had more babies, more wives worked for pay, too. More than a third of all adult women were in the labor force.

    Men monopolized the growing number of elite white-collar and unionized blue-collar positions, and their pay advanced faster than women’s. Average weekly earnings of employees in the male-dominated construction industry rose 62% to $113 in 1960;weekly earnings in a sector with many women, retail trade, rose 45% to $58.

    Historically, economic growth has been a popular method of solving poverty because it jibes with the American work ethic and because it often uses tax cuts and subsidies to businesses and the rich to spur investment and job creation. The benefits are supposed to trickle down. And a booming economy normally lifts people who are poor because they have not been working and earning, and it raises wages because demand for labor is up and employers must pay more to attract and keep workers. Also, increased output expands the income pie; if enough new income goes to the poor in the form of jobs and higher wages, the poverty rate will fall.

    And fall it did in the 1950s. The proportion of the U.S. population that was poor declined from 30.2% in 1950 to 22.2% in 1960. (See figure A.2 in appendix 1.)⁶ It is hard to argue with the notion that the 50s, an age of limited government, had a good record against poverty. But is the case finished?

    What Made Poverty Fall in the 1950s?

    Higher earnings from the main breadwinner were a major factor lifting families above the poverty line.⁷ Increased earnings reflected growth in national output, productivity increases that made workers more efficient, and upward career moves. Some of the biggest advances in earnings came for blacks who migrated from the southern countryside to northern cities. It did not take much to rise above a sharecropper’s annual earnings of $300. The poverty rate for African American southern families was 74.6% in 1949;for African American northern families in 1959 it was 31.7%. This did not mean that all was well for black migrants, but average incomes were higher.⁸

    Migration, occupational advances, and earnings growth depended, in part, on general economic growth. Why was economic growth healthy in the 50s? Pent-up consumer demand from the 30s and early 40s still fueled the private sector, but government also helped. Spending on the Korean War (1950–53) created an economic boom; spending on highways employed thousands, and highways facilitated commerce and suburban construction. The G.I. Bill subsidized education and homes for millions of families. Eisenhower went along with increases in Social Security, the minimum wage, and unemployment compensation. He talked of limited government, and Treasury Secretary George Humphrey lauded the free market, but government jobs at all levels were growing twice as fast as all nonagricultural jobs. Growth was working, but government spending fueled it.

    Growth, migration, and training did not directly help groups that were likely to be out of the labor force. Two such groups were older Americans and female heads of household who wished to stay home with their children. Both groups grew in the 50s, and they made up almost half the American poor (figure 1.1). Each had some claim on public support, the aged because they had once worked, and female heads because they were raising children. Were government payments curing poverty in these two groups?¹⁰

    The American welfare state seemed backward. As historian James Patterson put it, Europeans tried to maximize coverage and minimize the stigma of accepting public aid . . . [Americans] sought to cut expenses and exclude from the rolls all people considered able to care for themselves.¹¹ Nevertheless, governments provided income to female-headed families, the blind and disabled, the unemployed, and the elderly. Spending on Social Security and disability insurance (the Old Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance program [OASDI]) increased ten times in the 50s. The number of families on welfare (Aid to Dependent Children [ADC], which later became Aid to Families with Dependent Children [AFDC]) inched up from 644,000 to 787,000, and one economist claimed that transfer payments lifted 30% of the poor out of poverty in 1961. But monthly payments to welfare families still averaged only $108 a month in 1960, roughly $1,300 a year. That was extreme poverty. Especially in states like Mississippi, where annual payments were only several hundred dollars, welfare did not cure poverty.¹²

    Figure 1.1. Poor Families by Type of Head of Household, 1959

    Source: Based on data in Herman P. Miller, Rich Man, Poor Man (New York: Thomas Y. Crowell Co., 1964), 65–66.

    With Social Security things were different. The recipient population multiplied, and benefits were liberalized four times in the 1950s. Average benefits increased from 59% to 83% of the poverty line for older couples. A retired female worker on her own was paid only $626 a year in 1957;she was probably still poor. Couples with Social Security and other income, however, were less likely to be poor by the end of the 50s.¹³

    Total beneficiaries ofADC and OASDI jumped from 2 million to 18 million over 1945–60.¹⁴ Although more people were being helped, the welfare state may have been hardening the division between a deserving poor (the elderly) and a less deserving poor (welfare families). The former were already getting a better deal. Whether the split would congeal would be determined by interplay of ideas, organizations, and politics. Could liberals offer a vision that combined generous support not only for unemployed and retired blue-collar whites but also for poor African Americans? Would the welfare poor be degraded and isolated?¹⁵

    Seeds of a Debate

    Although the economy was generally strong, a third to a fifth of the population was poor, and another fifth was on the edge of poverty. That was enough for a debate about economic policy. The welfare system was doing little to lift families out of poverty. That the poorest 40% of families received only 15% of all national income challenged the popular idea that everyone was middle class. Although they did not increase as in later decades, wealth inequalities were wide; the richest 1% of all adults held 33% of all assets by 1962.¹⁶

    For most of the decade questions like these were smothered by Cold War anticommunism, good feelings about prosperity, and conservatism in the professions. Anticommunism made it dangerous to be critical of America, and prosperity seemed to make it unnecessary. Not only did many Americans think that socialism and Marxism meant low living standards and totalitarianism; many believed also that affluence was eliminating class divisions.¹⁷ While it was not surprising that politicians and business apologists were uncritical of capitalism, the retreat of critical thought and broad sympathy among some social scientists and social workers was troubling. Even in the Great Depression, most social scientists were not particularly radical on economic questions about class and capitalism, but in the late 40s and 50s, having to fight the Cold War by affirming American virtues blinded otherwise intelligent scholars. In 1955, prominent sociologists David Riesman and Nathan Glazer found no underprivileged except in enclaves in the southern Alleghenies and the rural Deep South. Poverty, in other words, was not much of a problem. Sociologist Robert Nisbet declared in 1959 that the United States was largely an egalitarian society: The conception of class is largely obsolete. For many writers America had but one class, a huge middle stratum running from the lowliest worker to the richest coupon clipper. Such a formulation drowned the worries of the working class in a sea of affluence and shoved the poor out of the mainstream.¹⁸

    Not long ago intellectual historian Richard Pells praised Riesman, William Whyte, and other 1950s social critics who gave our language catchy phrases like the lonely crowd,the power elite, and the organization man. These writers were creative thinkers, but their creativity flowed in narrow channels, as did their collective obsession with the identity problems of the middle class. Few investigated the economic insecurities of the working class or the poor. This myopia of the intellectuals narrowed social policy in the 50s.¹⁹

    While some in the helping professions worked with federal officials and union lobbyists to expand the social welfare state, many in the field of social work were more interested in the psychiatric rehabilitation of the needy.²⁰ But there were two noteworthy governmental initiatives against poverty. In 1956 Democratic governor Averell Harriman of New York appointed a committee on low-income problems. Its job-training experiments for the unemployed and underemployed and other pilot projects apparently improved the lives of 4,500 poor people. It is difficult to judge the effectiveness of those programs,but the Harriman effort anticipated programs of the 1960s by using training programs to restore chronic welfare cases to economic self-sufficiency, by targeting one of the main causes of substandard incomes, racial discrimination, and by establishing community development projects to focus local resources on the poverty problem. Most of all, the experiment showed that it was possible to crack the crust of complacency.²¹

    The other initiative emerged from a congressional subcommittee on low-income families headed by Senator John Sparkman of Alabama. In 1949, the subcommittee pioneered the effort to develop explanations for poverty that were both humane and constricting. Economic deprivation, in this view, afflicted groups that, for reasons ranging from race and age to regional economic decline, were left behind as the economy expanded. Ending poverty was a problem not, as in the thirties, of the mainstream millions who were poor because of a faulty economy but of people who had social handicaps or faced discrimination that kept them out of a prosperous economy.

    This handicapping approach was based on realities; there was, for example, an association between poverty and female-headed families, and race, sex, and age discrimination limited opportunity. But if the handicapping emphasis became the main approach to poverty, larger economic causes affecting millions of working-class Americans would be ignored. Furthermore, while it touched on such deep problems as racial discrimination, the handicapping model risked marginalizing poverty. In class terms, this categorical approach pushed aside the idea of a big working class of unemployed and employed but vulnerable people and created a one-class-plus model: most Americans were employed, successful, and middle class; outside this huge class were the poor, people who lacked drive or faced special impediments that kept them from pulling themselves up by their bootstraps.

    The Sparkman committee seemed to reflect this one-class-plus approach, which risked marginalizing the poor and ignoring the working class.²² An alternative came from a group of social workers and charity leaders who offered Sparkman’s committee a study of one hundred low-income families in the early 50s. Their idea of the poor included fathers who are heads of small enterprises such as a machine shop, a pickle works, laundries. Others are salaried employees or skilled or semiskilled wage earners—for example a goldsmith, a mold maker, tool and sheet-metal workers, bakers, truckmen, postmen . . . GIs on the way up; mothers keeping broken homes intact; together with a score of farm families and operators, sharecroppers and migratory workers. . . . Over a fourth of the urban breadwinners were skilled workers . . . one third of our urban family breadwinners had worked a full year . . . without earning as much as $2000.²³ This was a helpful way to picture the low-income population—as a broad spectrum of occupations and conditions, including many regularly employed people. It suggested a large, durable political constituency for egalitarian politics. Whether a broad or narrow view would frame policy remained to be seen.

    Recession and Unemployment Raise Questions: The Late 1950s

    Throughout much of the decade conservatives tarred government social programs as communism, but in the late 1950s, anticommunism weakened. The Cold War with the Soviet Union continued, but in new forms; the Russians beat the Americans when they launched the Sputnik satellite in October 1957, and that fueled a national debate about American schools.²⁴

    Other events put equality and poverty in the

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1