Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

The Rice Economies: Technology and Development in Asian Societies
The Rice Economies: Technology and Development in Asian Societies
The Rice Economies: Technology and Development in Asian Societies
Ebook438 pages6 hours

The Rice Economies: Technology and Development in Asian Societies

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

The contrast in the rate of growth between Western and Eastern societies since 1800 has caused Asian societies to be characterized as backward and resistant to change, though until 1600 or so certain Asian states were technologically far in advance of Europe. The Rice Economies, drawing on original source materials, examines patterns of technological and social evolution specific to East-Asian wet-rice economies in order to clarfiy some general historical trends in economic development.

This title is part of UC Press's Voices Revived program, which commemorates University of California Press's mission to seek out and cultivate the brightest minds and give them voice, reach, and impact. Drawing on a backlist dating to 1893, Voices Revived makes high-quality, peer-reviewed scholarship accessible once again using print-on-demand technology. This title was originally published in 1994.
The contrast in the rate of growth between Western and Eastern societies since 1800 has caused Asian societies to be characterized as backward and resistant to change, though until 1600 or so certain Asian states were technologically far in advance of Eur
LanguageEnglish
Release dateApr 28, 2023
ISBN9780520914933
The Rice Economies: Technology and Development in Asian Societies
Author

Francesca Bray

Francesca Bray is Professor of Anthropology at the University of California, Santa Barbara, and author of The Rice Economies: Technology and Development in Asian Societies (California, 1994).

Related to The Rice Economies

Related ebooks

Asian History For You

View More

Related articles

Related categories

Reviews for The Rice Economies

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    The Rice Economies - Francesca Bray

    The Rice Economies

    For Sandy

    The Rice Economies

    Technology and Development

    in Asian Societies

    FRANCESCA BRAY

    University of California Press

    Berkeley • Los Angeles • London

    University of California Press

    Berkeley and Los Angeles, California

    University of California Press, Ltd.

    London, England

    © 1986 by Francesca Bray

    First Paperback Printing 1994

    Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

    Bray, Francesca.

    The rice economies: technology and development in Asian societies I Francesca Bray.

    p. cm.

    Originally published: Oxford; New York: Blackwell, 1986. With a new pref.

    Includes bibliographical references and index.

    ISBN 0-520-08620-1

    1. Rice trade—Asia. 2. Asia—Economic conditions—1945-

    3. Agriculture—Economic aspects—Asia. I. Title.

    HD9066.A7B73 1994

    338.1'7318'095—dc20 93-41318

    CIP

    Printed in the United States of America 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

    The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1984. ®

    Contents

    Contents

    Figures and tables

    Chinese dynasties

    Japanese eras

    Preface

    Acknowledgements

    Introduction

    Eurocentric models of historical change

    An alternative model?

    The significance of a model of development for rice economies

    1 The rice-plant: diversity and intensification

    The origins of Asian rice

    Natural characteristics of rice

    Selection techniques

    2 Paths of technical development

    Building new fields

    Raising yields

    Labour productivity and the mechanisation question

    3 Water Control

    Water control and institutions: the debate

    A technical classification of water control systems

    Gravity-fed irrigation networks

    Ponds, tanks and reservoirs

    Contour canals

    'Creek ’ irrigation18

    Pump irrigation schemes

    Patterns of growth and change

    4 Rice and the wider economy

    ‘Skill-oriented’ and ‘mechanical’ technologies

    The specificity of wet-rice agriculture

    Uniformity and systemic change

    Monoculture and markets

    Economic diversification

    Petty commodity production and rural industrialisation

    5 Development

    Some basic issues

    Labour and capital

    The historical experience: the predominance of labour and the Japanese model'

    Choice of technological inputs

    Capital investment

    Productivity of labour and capital

    Expertise and participation

    6 Peasant, landlord and state: changes in relations of production

    Conflict, cooperation and control

    Historical changes in relations of production

    'Feudal’ relations and frontier zones

    Smallholder economies: expansion and stagnation

    Egalitarianism or differentiation: the impact of capitalism

    Land and landlessness

    Land to the tiller

    Group farming

    Socialist land reform

    APPENDIX A: The Western model

    APPENDIX B: The historical experience of China

    APPENDIX C: The Japanese experience

    Notes

    References

    Glossary

    Index

    Figures and tables

    Figures

    1.1 Area of origin of domesticated rice 9

    1.2 The rice-plant 14

    1.3 Harvesting-knife, ketaman, used in Kelantan 21

    2.1 Bunded field: clay model from a Han grave 31

    2.2 Poldered field illustrated in the Shoushi tongkao 36

    2.3 Poldered field in the 1930s in the Yangzi Delta 37

    2.4 A square-pallet chain-pump 39

    2.5 The Tomita estate 40

    2.6 A ‘seedling-horse’ 47

    2.7 Response to nitrogen fertiliser 50

    3.1 Land productivity and irrigation ratio 63

    3.2 General plan of Angkor 74

    3.3 Han grave-model of irrigation pond and rice-field 78

    3.4 Bamboo aqueduct 82

    3.5 Wooden flume 84

    3.6 Irrigation systems in the Chieng Mai Basin 86

    3.7 The Fish Snout at Dujiangyan 89

    3.8 Percentage of cultivated land in China under irrigation 110

    4.1 KADA timetable for rice cultivation 123

    4.2 Labour inputs in single- and double-cropping areas in Province Wellesley, Malaysia 126

    4.3 Picking mulberry leaves to feed silkworms 133

    5.1 Labour demands on a holding in Shinshü in 1823 151

    Tables

    2.1 Rice production in the Burmese Delta 43

    2.2 Relative contributions of area and yield to total growth in rice production during the period 1955-73 43

    2.3 Rice yields in East and Southeast Asia 52

    3.1 Rice production at Satingpra, fourth to fourteenth centuries 70

    3.2 Main canals along the Aka River (Northeast Honshü) in the T okugawa period 87

    3.3 Rice in French Cochinchina 95

    4.1 F arm sizes in Asia 116

    4.2 Underemployment in single- and double-cropping rice areas in

    Province Wellesley, Malaysia 126

    4.3 Non-padi income as proportion of net padi income in KADA and MADA (1979/80) 131

    5.1 Population densities in Asia 144

    5.2 Income shares of decile groups in Asia 144

    5.3 Rice yields and labour inputs 149

    5.4 Rice yields and labour inputs in Japan 154

    5.5 Proportion of hired labour used in rice production 163

    5.6 Mechanisation in Korea and Japan 166

    Chinese dynasties

    Zhou: 1066-221 BC

    Spring and Autumn period: 722-481 BC

    Warring States: r.403-221 BC

    Qin: 221-206 BC

    Han: 206 BC-AD 220

    Three Kingdoms: 220-80

    Six Dynasties: 222-589

    Northern and Southern Dynasties: 317-589

    Sui: 581-618

    Tang: 618-907

    Five Dynasties: 907-60

    Northern Song: 960-1127

    Southern Song: 1127-1279

    Yuan: 1279-1368

    Ming: 1368-1644

    Qing: 1644-1911

    Republic of China: 1911-49

    Japanese eras

    (There is little agreement as to the exact nomenclature and dates of the periods of Japanese history; the following is a rough guide.)

    Jõmon: To c.200 BC

    Yayoi: 200 BC-AD 250

    Kofun: 250-552

    Yamato: 300-710

    Asuka: 552-645

    Nara: 645-794

    Heian: 794-1185

    Kamakura: 1185-1392

    Muromachi: 1473-1568

    Momoyama: 1568-1600

    Tokugawa: 1600-1868

    Modern: 1868 to date

    Meiji: 1868-1912

    Taisho: 1912-26

    Shõwa 1926-

    Preface

    This book is a social history written from a materialist perspective. Starting from the assumption that one cannot understand the history of agrarian societies without a grasp of how the concrete conditions of agricultural production evolved, I trace the development of the technology of wet-rice agriculture in East and Southeast Asia from prehistoric to modern times, and link this development to social and economic change.

    As a macroregion, East and Southeast Asia is as diverse as Braudel’s Mediterranean (1972) or Chaudhuri’s Indian Ocean (1990). The unity I attribute to these multifarious societies derives from their shared reliance on the same staple crop, rice, with its technical logic of development. From Burma to the Philippines and from Bali to Korea, rice is indisputably the most important food-grain in the economy. Unlike the rice regions of South Asia, where for climatic and/or topographical reasons effective water control is extremely difficult (Farmer 1981), in all the societies of East and Southeast Asia small-scale irrigation has been a crucial factor in the development of one of the most land- and labour-intensive farming systems in the world. This I contrast to a Western model that has taken quite the opposite direction.

    In the case of the staple crop that feeds the population and fills the coffers of landowners and the state, the development of the social institutions which depend upon its supply is inseparable from the development of the agricultural system that produces the crop. Rice and wheat have quite different characteristics and requirements: farming systems based on these crops are presented with a different range of technical choices, and they experience different patterns of social and political development in consequence.

    I start this study with an analysis of techniques and proceed to an analysis of social formations because I think this method can throw new light on Asian history. The past two centuries of Western supremacy have promoted the view that there is only one trajectory of technical development that constitutes real progress. Inherent in this model are capitalist criteria of efficiency consolidated during the Western experience of industrialisation and agricultural development: increasing output and profits are produced through scale economies, mechanisation and the progressive substitution of capital for labour. We have internalised the emblems of progress found in this model: we all learn at school that a tractor is more advanced than an iron plough, which is more advanced than a hoe; a thousand-acre farm specialising in wheat and run by three individuals is more efficient than a half-acre farm growing sixteen different crops and taking up much of the labour of a family of eight.

    The Western attachment to teleology usually works in our own favour: other societies come out as inferior, as failures. From Hegel and Marx on, China, for example, has been stigmatised as a society which failed to progress or to experience historical change until forcibly subjected to Western influence. Even Joseph Needham’s writings in Science and Civilisation in China (to which I contributed [Bray, 1984]), sinophile and critical of Western claims as they are, are inspired by the essentially negative ‘Needham question’: until about 1500 China was ahead of Europe in many branches of science and technology, so why did China fail to develop capitalism, industrialisation and the scientific revolution? Specialists and comparatists have debated the relative importance of various ‘inhibiting factors’, as if capitalism was the evolutionary goal of all healthy societies. The language of failure is particularly salient in the work of economic historians, who do not hesitate to speak of China from about 1000 to 1949 in terms of stagnation, involution or ‘growth without development’ (e.g., Elvin 1973; Huang 1990). Yet as Perkins (1969) demonstrates, despite the natural disasters and devastating wars that interrupted the otherwise steady growth of a huge population, between 1000 and 1800 Chinese agriculture developed and expanded sufficiently rapidly to maintain, and sometimes improve, overall living standards. These centuries of economic and social continuity require positive explanation—stability is not something that can be taken for granted.

    Here I am not concerned with Asia’s ‘failure’ to be like the West, though in Chapter 4 I do discuss how the organisation of labour and investment between wet-rice agriculture and other productive sectors evolved in ways that were unpropitious for industrial forms of organisation. My main concern is to provide materials for understanding Asian societies, not as evolutionary failures or stagnating ponds of surplus humanity, but as societies which work in different ways from those of Europe, and to which our accustomed teleologies cannot usefully be applied. I consider the historical analysis of an absolutely fundamental technology, the technology of staple food production, an important contribution to this endeavour. I also think it is a crucial factor in understanding how the Asian rice economies are evolving today.

    I first started thinking about the specificity of wet-rice economies during a year’s fieldwork in Malaysia in 1976, when the discrepancies between much of the development literature and my observations at the village level set me reflecting on the different effects the Green Revolution was having on the rice and wheat regions of Asia. My ambitions to extend my hypothesis historically grew when I returned from Malaysia to continue work on a general history of Chinese agriculture. I noticed that in North China, where dry cereals were the staple crops, a pattern of technological development and relations of production rather similar to that of late medieval Western Europe started to emerge in the early centuries A.D. It was characterised by the formation of large estates that were centrally managed and heavily dependent upon economies of scale, such as the use of animal-powered machinery. The owners of these estates successfully resisted repeated state efforts to disestablish them (Bray 1980). But nomadic invasions and civil unrest pushed the political centre south to China’s rice regions, and although large-scale ownership of land persisted throughout China’s history, large-scale management became a thing of the past. The Chinese state, whether out of benevolence or self-interest, traditionally supported the rights of the individual peasant against aristocratic or gentry landowners. This position was easier to sustain when rice cultivation was the mainstay of the economy because even though land-ownership might be concentrated, small family farms predominated. Peasant farmers were easier to tax than the gentry, and the persistence of peasant farming must surely have been a factor in the longevity of the Chinese empire. But what was it that allowed peasant farming to survive in the teeth of gentry ambitions? Government encouragement was not enough, as we can tell from what happened during the early dynasties in North China. Unlike Gourou (1984:6), who denies any determining influence of rice cultivation on the societies in which it is practised, I feel sure that important reasons for the survival of peasant farming must lie in the basic conditions of rice production (Bray 1984).

    Japanese historians have long used the notion of a rice-growing culture as a fundamental explanation of the specificities of Japanese society (Kanazawa 1971; Tamaki 1979). At the time when I was pursuing fieldwork in Malaysia there were already strong advocates for substituting a ‘Japanese model’ for the ‘Western model’ in the agricultural development of Asia’s rice regions (Ishikawa 1967; Ishii 1978a). Since I first published this book in 1986, other Asian historians have started to explore the long-term demographic and economic characteristics peculiar to rice-based societies (Hayami and Tsubouchi 1990). But most economic history remains wedded to the Western bias of capitalist teleology, privileging labour productivity and profits in its interpretations. Today it seems to me that both the political and the environmental reasons for rejecting such values are overwhelming.

    When I completed this book eight years ago I hoped it would serve a dual purpose. The first was to go beyond historical analyses of Asia as ‘not-Europe’. Cultural and political historians have so far been among the most creative contributors to this project. But the material conditions of life should not be neglected in these analyses, for they are as fundamental in defining a society as religion or political ideas. New criteria are needed for evaluating systems of production as well as systems of thought. The study of technology in this book questions Westernbiased criteria and models. I hope that soon there will be many more studies of productive technologies that diverge from Western norms, bringing original and stimulating perspectives to bear on the articulations between production and power, and transcending the language of involution, stagnation and failure.

    My second purpose in writing this book was to take history through the present and into the future, to provide an analysis of the social and technical frameworks which Asian agricultural modernisation programmes were and still are attempting to transform. At that time I felt that perhaps the most striking and pertinent feature common to Asia’s rice economies, as described in both historical documents and contemporary literature, was that although the ownership of land tended to become concentrated when methods were improved and production increased, economies of scale did not apply as in the Western model, and the basic unit of management remained the small family farm. I expected that this would make the Western-style modernisation of established wet-rice zones particularly difficult and contentious. This has indeed proved to be the case, even in wealthy and technically advanced countries, as recent literature on the deepening of Japan’s agricultural crisis shows (Tweeten 1993).

    There are, of course, certain rice-regions even in Asia where Western patterns occur. The Muda scheme in Malaysia, where processes of class differentiation have been so vividly described by Scott (1985), is one example. My explanation is that this pattern is most likely to occur in areas, like Muda, where rice farming was introduced fairly recently and where fields were initially constructed on a large scale, so that there are few infrastructural barriers to plans involving large-scale mechanisation and farm consolidation. One might say that Muda’s infrastructure is closer to those of Australia and California, where enormous rice fields constructed since the last world war, levelled by laser and sown from planes, use minimal labour to produce yields that are among the highest in the world. But long-established rice systems have proved extremely resistant to the transition to modern large-scale farming, which may perhaps prove to be a blessing, given the disastrous predicament of world agriculture today and the urgent need to adopt alternative strategies.

    Eight years after this book was first published, I now see it as serving a third purpose. I was delighted to find that some of the most enthusiastic supporters of this work were ecologists and environmentalists working on sustainable development. Environmental concerns have started to penetrate even the international development agencies. Increasing numbers of people now question the Western farming model, which, as science and technology advance, is becoming even more wasteful and destructive of the environment and of rural life (Friedmann 1990). Ecologists tend to seek inspiration for viable alternatives from small groups as yet untainted by Western ideas and input, for instance horticulturists in Amazonia or upland farmers in the Yucatan. Yet it is extremely unlikely that their environmentally impeccable techniques could be extended to support large populations or that their farming methods could be transposed. Nor could they solve another of the most urgent problems of our times: how to improve the livelihood of the ever-growing numbers of rural poor.

    According to the World Bank, ‘the greatest numbers of the poor, including the very poorest, are found overwhelmingly in rural areas’ (1990:33). Attempts to address this problem by modernising farming have usually just made things worse: cereal monoculture, mechanisation and expensive inputs marginalise poor farmers, displace labour and reduce alternative economic opportunities. Surely an obvious improvement is to encourage the development of agricultural systems which absorb labour and encourage economic diversification (Bray 1992; Bray forthcoming). The history of Asia’s rice economies shows that even without chemicals and laboratory-bred seeds, intensive ricefarming has the potential to provide a lasting basis for a diversified rural economy, feeding and providing employment for large populations. I do not, of course, advocate that we try to convert Bangladesh into eighteenth-century Japan, or that we turn the clock back nine centuries in China’s Yangzi Delta. But I do think that Asian rice, as well as other farming systems where land and labour are or have been used intensively, should be carefully studied for indications as to how rural economies could best be revitalised to meet both environmental and humanitarian needs.

    I am grateful to the British Academy and the Royal Society for financing a field trip to Malaysia in 1976- 7, to the British Council and to the Universities’ China Committee for supporting a study tour to China in 1980 and to the Leverhulme Trust for providing a most generous two-year fellowship in 1982 -4, which enabled me to spend several months in Asia. The British Academy helped me again in 1982 with a Wolfson Fellowship which allowed me to spend several months in Paris working on archival material. Dr Joseph Needham and the East Asian History of Science Library (now the Needham Research Institute) in Cambridge provided me with unfailing support throughout.

    It would be impossible to thank by name all those who have given me help and advice in this project. The villagers of Bunut Susu, and especially their imam, Encik Abdul Rahman bin Haji Suleiman, were its inspiration; it was through the kindness of the Kemubu Agricultural Development Authority staff and their economist, Puan Rohaini Zakaria, that I made their acquaintance. In Singapore I received generous help from the staff of the Institute for Southeast Asian Studies; in Kuala Lumpur from Wan Ahmad Radzi and Puan Fadillah Ibrahim and their families; in Kota Baru from Datuk Haji Yussuf Bangs, Encik Johan Arif and Robert and Pauline Whyte. In Penang the staff of the Centre for Policies Research kindly allowed me access to their invaluable collection. In Hong Kong I was given help and encouragement by, among others, Peter and Ei-Yoke Lisowski, Mr and Mrs P. L. Lam and George Hicks, who was most generous in providing material from his collection on the economies of Southeast Asia. In 1977 a visit to Taiwan was made fruitful through the good offices of the Joint Committee for Rural Reconstruction, and Professor T. T. Chang of the International Rice Research Institute gave me valuable assistance in the Philippines. A study tour of China in 1980 was arranged through the kindness of Academia Sinica; to that organisation, and to all the distinguished scholars of agricultural development and history who kindly spared time to discuss their work with an undistinguished foreigner, I am grateful. In Japan I must mention Professors Hayashi Takeshi, Kojima Reiitsu and Tada Hirokazu and their colleagues at the Institute of Developing Economies and Professors Ichimura Shinichi, Ishii Yoneo and Tsubouchi Yoshihiro of the Institute of Southeast Asian Studies in Kyoto, as well as Professors Katõ Yuzo and Nakaoka Tetsurõ and Drs Fujimoto Akimi and Christian Daniels, all of whom were kind enough to discuss my work with me.

    At the Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique in Paris, where I worked on the final stages of this book, I was fortunate in the encouragement of my directors, M. Lucien Bernot and M. Jacques Gernet. In Cambridge, Ben Farmer and Sir Joseph Hutchinson gave me much expert advice, and my colleagues at the Needham Research Institute, Gregory Blue and Timothy Brook, helped keep my feet on the Chinese ground. Sean Magee was my guardian angel at Basil Blackwell and Charlene Woodcock at the University of California Press. Without Sandy Robertson this book would never have been written, and my gratitude goes beyond words.

    University of California, Santa Barbara

    September 1993

    Additional references

    Braudel, Fernand (1972): The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II, Harper and Row, New York.

    Bray, F. (1992): ‘Population, agricultural intensification and economic diversification’, in Lars O. Hansson and Britta Jungen (eds), Human Responsibility and Global Change, Institute of Human Ecology, University of Göteborg Press, Göteborg: 99-114.

    — (forthcoming): ‘Rice economies and agricultural development’, Scientific American.

    Chaudhuri, K. N. (1990): Asia before Europe: Economy and Civilisation of the Indian Ocean from the Rise of Islam to 1750, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York.

    Friedmann, Harriet (1990): ‘Family wheat farms and Third World diets: a paradoxical relationship between unwaged and waged labor’, in Jane L. Collins and Martha Gimenez (eds), Work without Wages: Domestic Labor and Self-Employment Within Capitalism, State University of New York Press, Albany: 193-213.

    Hayami, Akira and Yoshihiro Tsubouchi (eds) (1990): Economic and Demographic Development in Rice Producing Societies, Proceedings of the Tenth International Economic History Conference, Leuven University Press, Leuven.

    Huang, Philip (1990): The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the YangziDelta, 1350-1988, Stanford University Press, Stanford, Calif.

    Scott, James C. (1985): Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance, Yale University Press, New Haven.

    Tweeten, Luther, Cynthia L. Dishon, Wen S. Chern, Naraomi Imamura and Masaru Morishima (eds) (1993): Japanese and American Agriculture: Tradition and Progress in Conflict, Westview Press, Boulder, Colo.

    World Bank (1990): World Development Report 1990: Poverty, Oxford University Press, New York.

    Acknowledgements

    The author and the publishers would like to thank the following for permission to use figures and tables from, or base figures and tables on, their own copyright material. Dr T. T. Chang, International Rice Research Institute, Manila, for figure 1.1, redrawn from his article ‘The origin, evolution, dissemination and diversification of African and Asian Rices’, Euphytica 1976; Routledge and Kegan Paul, London, for figure 2.3, from Hsiao-T’ung Fei, Peasant Life in China: A Field Study of Country Life in the Yangtze Valleys Professor Keiji Nagahara, Department of Economics, Hitotsubashi University, for figure 2.5, from Hideo Kuroda, ‘Chusei nõgyõ jutsu no yõsõ’, in Nagahara and Yamaguchi (eds), Nõgyõ, nõsankako (Nihon Hyoronsha, Tokyo, 1983; International Rice Research Institute, Manila, for figure 2.7, from R. Barker, ‘Yield and fertiliser input’, IRRf 1978; Professor Shigeru Ishikawa, Aoyama University, Tokyo, for figure 3.1, from Ishikawa, Economic Development in Asian Perspective (Tokyo, 1967); Professor Yoneo Ishii, Centre for South East Asian Studies, Kyoto University, for figure 3.6, from Yoshiro Kaida, ‘Irrigation and drainage: present and future’, in Ishii (ed.), Thailand: A Rice-Growing Society (Hawaii UP, 1978); University of Malaya, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia, for figure 4.2, from J. T. Purcal, Rice Economy: Employment and Income in Malaysia (EastWest Center Press, Honolulu, 1972); Board of Trustees, Stanford University Press, for figure 5.1, from Thomas C. Smith, The Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan (Stanford UP, 1959); Dr Janice Stargardt, Cambridge Project on Ancient Civilization in South East Asia, for table 3.1, based on table 21 from Stargardt, Satingpra I: The Environmental and Economic Archaeology of South Thailand (Oxford and Singapore, 1983).

    Map 1 East and Southeast Asia

    Map 2 Central provinces of China

    Map 3 States of peninsular Malaysia (showing Muda and Kemubu regions)

    Introduction

    Eurocentric models of historical change

    European historical methodology has understandably been profoundly marked by the growth of capitalism, but it is doubtful to what extent models derived from Europe’s highly specific experience are applicable to other parts of the world. Historians attempting to interpret Asian history find themselves wrestling with such intractable categories as ‘feudalism’ or ‘peasants’ which, despite their reassuring vagueness, rarely seem to fit the case exactly. Evading the issue entirely, one long-standing Western tradition recognises the essential ‘otherness’ of Asian societies by attributing to them a timelessness and unchanging quality encapsulated in the concept of the Asian Mode of Production. Others, recognising that all societies change eventually, and faced with the necessity of accounting for such awkward facts as the development of commerce and commodity production in pre-modern India and China, or industrialisation and the emergence of capitalism in Meiji Japan, have preferred to think of Asia as following basically the same path as Europe, but less successfully and less rapidly. Thus Marxist historians in China and Japan categorise a vast span of Chinese history (from about 200 BC to 1911 or 1949) as feudal, with ‘sprouts of capitalism’ emerging intermittently during the past four or five centuries but withering before they bore fruit (see Grove and Esherick 1980; Brook 1981). NonMarxist historians too, especially when explaining the failure to develop capitalism (or the contrary in the case of Japan), usually measure off Asian societies point for point against a European model of development, to see where they are lacking (Elvin 1973; Tang 1979; Yamamura 1979; Jones 1981).

    Both of these methods are essentially negative, the one denying the occurrence of any significant change, the other obscuring the specificity of non-European societies. If we look only for what is typical of Europe, the significant features of a less familiar society may simply escape our notice. Over the last four centuries European society has been completely transformed, and advanced capitalism has accustomed us to a breakneck pace of change. By comparison it is not surprising that Asian societies seem to have stood still. Yet where adequate documents exist it is not difficult to show that in Asian societies too the forces of production were expanded and relations of production transformed — though not always in the way one might expect. The difficulty lies in accounting for the nature of such changes: if the dynamics of change differ from those we have identified as operating in European history, then it is not surprising that our traditional models fail adequately to interpret change in non-European societies, or even to acknowledge its existence.

    While it is easy to appreciate that eurocentric models will generally prove inadequate to explain the evolution of non-European societies, it is not so easy to construct appropriate alternatives. One important obstacle is our failure (in the main) to recognise the relativity of our conception of technological progress. Changes in technology are clearly one key to explicating economic history, though of course there is considerable debate as to the exact degree to which technological development determines, affects, or is simply an expression of changes in the social formation. But what exactly constitutes technological development? Here all our doubts seem to evaporate. Philosophers like Gehlen (1965) and Habermas (1971) have pointed out the immanent connection between the contemporary evaluation of technology and the ‘rationality’ (in the Weberian sense) that prevails in capitalist society. To be more specific, in a society where relatively scarce and expensive wage-labour is the basis of production, technical progress is largely evaluated in terms of efficiency in replacing labour. Yet this highly specific model of technological advance is generally presumed to be universal in its application. Although one can easily envisage situations in which different criteria might apply, little attempt has been made to hypothesise alternative paths of technological development or to examine the social and economic implications of such differences.

    If we consider the case of agriculture, we find that technological progress is generally construed as a sequence from primitive tools like digging-sticks or hoes to more complex instruments like ploughs or harrows, culminating in the mechanical sophistication of tractors, combine-harvesters and crop-spraying aeroplanes. To this one would add the application of scientific methods to such agricultural procedures as crop selection, nutrition and weeding, resulting in the laboratory breeding of new crop strains with desirable characteristics, and the industrial production of chemical fertilisers, herbicides and pesticides. ‘Progress’ seems to lie chiefly in the increasingly efficient substitution of alternative forms of energy for human labour. Now labour-saving changes in agriculture have three possible effects: first, they may enable the same number of workers to bring larger areas of land under cultivation; secondly, they may enable the same area to be cultivated by fewer workers, thus liberating the surplus labour for some other employment; and thirdly, they may allow the same area of land to be more intensively cultivated without increasing the number of workers.

    The first type of change is of particular importance where land is plentiful and labour scarce, as it has been in much of the New World; it is not surprising, for example, that it was in underpopulated Australia and the United States, as the world market for wheat expanded in the later nineteenth century, that the reaper-binder and the combine-harvester were developed (Jones 1979). The second type of change is important where labour is in high demand, scarce and expensive, as was the case in Europe in the early stages of the development of capitalism. As Boserup (1981: 99) says: ‘There was usually keen competition for scarce labour [between agriculture and manufactures], and most often agriculture lost in this competition. Nothing could be more inappropriate than to characterise the European economy in this period as a labour surplus economy. On the contrary, one of the most serious problems in the period of pre-industrial urbanisation in Western and Central Europe was insufficiency of food production, due not to shortage of land, but to shortage of labour.’ In fact in the early stages of the ‘Agricultural Revolution’ demands for labour generally grew, as cropping frequency increased and as techniques became more intensive in response to the greater demand for agricultural produce (Chambers 1967). At first the greater demand for agricultural labour could be accommodated by population increase, but as industrialisation advanced and the

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1