Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia
Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia
Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia
Ebook664 pages8 hours

Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

This publication examines the need to expand social protection coverage of the informal sector to support working age productivity, reduce vulnerability, and improve economic opportunity. Case studies from Bangladesh, the People's Republic of China, India, Indonesia, Pakistan, the Philippines, and Thailand offer suggestions to close social protection gaps and recommend policy solutions to create equitable and inclusive social protection programs for informal workers.
LanguageEnglish
Release dateDec 1, 2016
ISBN9789292575663
Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia

Related to Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia

Related ebooks

Public Policy For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    Social Protection for Informal Workers in Asia - Asian Development Bank

    CHAPTER 1

    Designing and Delivering Social Protection Programs for Informal Sector Workers in Asia

    Michael Samson and Kaleigh Kenny

    Abstract

    Challenges in designing and delivering social protection systems that extend to informal sector workers arise not only from informal sector workers’ lack of access to traditional forms of social protection, but more generally from the heterogeneity of the sector itself. As a result, social protection programs that target informal sector workers must employ more creative and active forms of outreach than those used by formal sector programs.

    The success of social protection initiatives depends not only on their ability to protect beneficiaries from the negative impacts of the risks and vulnerabilities that they face, but also on their ability to facilitate achievement of broader development objectives such as equity, social inclusion, and fiscal sustainability. This requires coordinated effort at numerous levels of social protection policy formulation and implementation. Providing guidance on how social protection systems—regardless of whether these target formal or informal sector workers—should be conceptualized, formulated, and implemented requires a comprehensive approach that addresses requisite actions at the policy, program, and administrative levels.

    At the policy level, coordination is required among social protection policy and social protection programs, their sources of financing, and their institutional arrangements. At the program level, coordination is also needed between social protection programs that fulfill the surveys, covering specific policy areas where most micro, small, and medium-sized enterprise (MSME) workers lack social protection coverage, as well as programs that are complementary. Such coordination is required if coverage gaps are to be reduced and the impact of all social protection interventions deepened. The administrative level is the basic level of provision of social protection. It encompasses the day-to-day tasks of ensuring adherence to program design and implementing efficient, effective, and accessible delivery systems. The formulation and implementation of social protection programs for informal sector workers is often hampered by administrative and fiscal capacity constraints, as well as by the limitations of human and technical resources. However, despite limited capacity for administration and evaluation, it is very encouraging that several countries in Asia are able to design and implement effective social protection programs that target informal sector workers.

    Introduction

    Ensuring the availability of social protection to Asia’s large and growing informal sector labor force is one of the region’s major social policy challenges. As the informal sector comprises all economic activity that remains outside of the official institutional framework, it spans a broad spectrum of employment that includes street vendors, home-based workers, self-employed workers, and workers who are paid wages. For the most part, formal social protection programs, such as contributory pensions, health insurance, unemployment insurance, or disability benefits, do not cover these individuals.

    The informal sector comprises an estimated 40.0%–50.0% of Asia’s total labor force, with estimates reaching as high as 90.0% in some countries (Unni and Rani 2003). While informal sector workers account for a significant share of the region’s overall workforce, most are not covered by social protection programs, as these are more easily extended to the formally employed. Innovative design, targeting, and implementation of social protection programs adapted to the conditions of the informal sector are thus necessary to address the current exclusion of this large—yet nearly invisible—labor force from the formal social protection system.

    Challenges in designing and delivering social protection systems that extend to informal sector workers arise not only from their lack of access to traditional forms of social protection, but more generally from the heterogeneity of the sector itself. In short, the difficulties faced by governments in providing social protection to workers who lack requisite registration and documentation are compounded by the fact that the informal sector varies widely across industry lines, types of organizations, geographic locations, and salary ranges. The design of social protection programs that meet the requirements implicit in such heterogeneity must cover the informal sector’s entire range of activities and individuals. Further, social protection programs and systems that target this significant segment of the overall labor force must also employ more creative and active forms of outreach than those used by formal sector programs.

    The nature of informal sector employment differs substantially from that in the formal sector. Lacking contracts and documentation, workers in the informal economy face high levels of income and job insecurity, and are often subject to dangerous or unhealthy work environments. Further, if an individual becomes sick or injured working under these conditions, he or she has no access to income replacement through guaranteed unemployment or employment injury benefits. Comprehensive approaches to mitigating such risks and to promoting inclusive growth are required if social protection systems are to adequately respond to the specific conditions of informal sector workers and the vulnerabilities that they face.

    This chapter addresses considerations that must be taken into account when designing and implementing social protection programs and systems for informal sector workers in Asia. However, as the chapter addresses social protection systems that respond to contingencies that are likely to occur at the various stages of life regardless of the employment status of an individual, it does not exclude references to programs that benefit the formal sector labor force. This chapter perceives social protection as a requisite component of the overall development effort and social protection for informal sector workers as a subset of that component.

    Providing guidance on how social protection systems—regardless of whether these target formal or informal sector workers—should be conceptualized, formulated, and implemented requires a comprehensive approach that addresses requisite actions at the policy, program, and administrative levels. In addition to policy and program considerations as these relate to social protection, the quality of day-to-day administration of social protection programs greatly affects the degree to which these programs result in their intended beneficial impacts.

    This chapter details best practices at each level of design and implementation of social protection programs as a means of offering guidance on how these programs can best serve the requirements of informal sector workers. It thus incorporates examples of social protection programs and systems that address the vulnerabilities faced by informal sector workers in Asia.

    The Informal Sector in Asia

    The degree to which social protection is provided to informal sector workers varies widely across Asia. The factors that account for this variation include (i) share of the informal sector in the total labor force, (ii) amount of resources devoted to social protection, (iii) nature and design of social protection policy, and (iv) level of effort devoted to providing social protection to the most excluded members of society (Kabeer et al. 2010). There is similarly wide variation in the social protection programs and benefit delivery methods used to address the specific needs of informal sector workers.

    Broadly speaking, the informal sector comprises all economic activity that remains outside of the official institutional framework. Given this definition, informalization of the workforce can occur through self-employment, wage work in enterprises in both the formal and informal sectors, or home-based work. In 2003, the 17th International Conference of Labour Statisticians broadly defined the informal sector to include (i) own-account workers who work in their own informal sector enterprises; (ii) employers who work in their own informal sector enterprises, and contributing family members; (iii) members of informal producers’ cooperatives; (iv) employees holding informal sector jobs as defined by the employment relationship; and (v) own-account workers engaged in the production of food for final use by their own household (Rys 2013). Such a definition encompasses all workers outside of the formal regulatory environment, and therefore outside of the typical coverage of social services, rather than workers who are simply employed by informal sector enterprises or who work without employment contracts. This definition has broad implications for the design and coverage of social protection systems.

    There is wide variation in the level of informality in labor markets across Asia’s subregions and countries. East Asian countries have benefited from substantial economic growth in recent years, and have thus seen increasing levels of formalization of their labor markets. In contrast, while Southeast Asian countries are projected to experience substantial employment growth over the coming years, this growth has been coupled with a continued high incidence of vulnerable employment (i.e., 59.0% of all employment in 2013). Vulnerable employment comprises informal sector employment that lacks an income or employment guarantee, home-based work, and uncompensated household work, the latter disproportionately characterizing employment of women in the region (i.e., 63.1% for women as compared with 56.0% for men in 2013) (ILO 2014).

    In South Asia, the informal sector accounts for a relatively large share of the total labor market. For example, during 2009–2010, informal employment comprised 83.6% of all nonagriculture employment in India, and 78.4% in Pakistan, with similar corresponding figures for other South Asian countries.⁵ Such heavy reliance on the informal sector suggests a high level of income and employment insecurity in South Asia, a situation further exacerbated by low labor force participation rates, in large part due to differences in rates between genders. For example, while the region’s total labor force participation rate was 56.1% in 2012, it was 80.6% for men but only 30.4% for women (ILO 2014). Such statistics demonstrate that women are more likely than men to engage in uncompensated work at home, which is a form of vulnerable employment since women’s autonomy within a household or community is lessened by their lack of an independent income source.

    Thus, in tandem with expansion of the informal sector in many parts of developing Asia, the share of women and youth employed in the informal sector has increased. One component of the informal sector driving this trend is growth in subcontracted home-based work in manufacturing and services (Mehrotra and Biggeri 2002). While an increase in home-based work simultaneously encourages development of microenterprises by women, contractors looking to cut costs by outsourcing product manufacturing or service delivery also tend to exploit home-based workers. This outcome has caused the relative income and living standards of informal sector workers to deteriorate, as it diminishes their bargaining power with respect to wage offers (Kudva and Benería 2005).

    Youth are also disproportionately represented in the informal economy (Rys 2013). As individuals are increasingly able to work into their later years, fewer opportunities are left for youth who lack the requisite experience and skills for procuring formal sector employment. Their only alternative is work in the informal sector. However, engaging in low-skills activities may limit the opportunities available to youth for finding more productive forms of employment later in life.

    The 90th Session of the International Labour Conference identified the lack of representation and rights in the workplace and lack of social protection as key decent work deficits in the informal economy (Shrestha 1991). These deficits are due to the informal sector operating outside of legislation, such as factory or commercial acts and tax or social security laws (Chen, Jhabvala, and Lund 2001). This causes informal sector workers to be more vulnerable to shocks arising from job and income insecurity and unsafe working conditions. It makes them more vulnerable to contingencies such as illness, injury, or death. From a fiscal perspective, ultimate inclusion of untaxed workers’ wages in the social protection system would greatly ease the financing of social protection, as an insufficient tax base can diminish both the number and coverage of social protection initiatives.

    Although there are vast differences between most formal and informal sector enterprises, the two are often inextricably linked, as most segments of the informal economy have connections to production, trade, and services in the formal economy (Chen, Jhabvala, and Lund 2001). This notwithstanding, informal sector workers do not benefit from the rights afforded to those who work in the formal sector.

    Designing and Delivering Social Protection Programs for Informal Sector Workers: The Policy Level

    The primary goal of providing social protection to informal sector workers is to ensure that all individuals are able to access decent forms of work that sustain their livelihoods throughout their life cycles. Further, social protection can guarantee a minimum level of income and dignity that allows informal sector workers better protection against income shocks and other vulnerabilities.

    The success of social protection initiatives depends not only on their ability to protect beneficiaries from the negative impacts of the risks and vulnerabilities that they face, but on their ability to achieve broader development objectives as well, such as equity, social inclusion, and fiscal sustainability. As a result, social protection initiatives should focus on outcomes and establish incentives for beneficiaries that help ensure that these outcomes are achieved rather than narrowly perceiving social protection as a purely humanitarian initiative.

    Achieving the above objectives requires coordinated effort at various levels of social protection policy formulation and implementation. Figure 1.1 depicts these levels of operation of social protection policy. At the policy level, coordination is required between social protection policy on one hand and the social protection programs implemented, their sources of financing, and their institutional arrangements on the other.

    Figure 1.1: Three Levels of Formulation and Operation of Social Protection Systems

    Source: L. Rawlings and S. Murthy. 2013. Common Ground: UNICEF and World Bank Approaches to Building Social Protection Systems. http://www.unicef.org/socialpolicy/files/UNICEF-WB_systems_note_formatted.pdf

    At the level of the individual social protection program, coordination is required among social protection programs that fulfill the same function, as well as programs that are complementary. Such coordination at the program level is required if coverage gaps are to be reduced and the impact of all such interventions deepened. The administrative level—which is the basic level of provision of social protection—encompasses the day-to-day tasks of ensuring adherence to program design and implementing effective and accessible delivery systems.

    At the policy level, the primary task of formulating and operating social protection programs is embedding social protection into a system of coordinated financing and institutional arrangements. This requires the cooperation of many government ministries and numerous sources of financing.

    Unfortunately, this contrasts sharply with the current state of affairs at the policy level, in which provision of social protection is often hampered by fragmentation and inefficiency. This could be mitigated if the national government employs a framework for coordinating social protection initiatives and clearly defines the objectives of each program within a wider set of development objectives. Two frameworks are described below that can be used by national governments to establish coordinated, efficient social protection systems.

    Life Cycle Approach

    The life cycle approach to formulating social protection systems assumes that individuals face different risks and vulnerabilities at different stages of life, and that social protection can be designed in a way that addresses the risks that dominate each stage. This approach defines a life cycle as a period in which an individual’s level of vulnerability is constant, and the composition of the risks that the individual faces remains unchanged. An individual thus enters a new life cycle when the set of risks and certainties that define the level of vulnerability changes in a positive or negative way (Bonilla-García and Gruat 2003). Thus, life cycle changes that result from negative shocks in social or economic status cause an individual to enter a new life cycle marked by an increased level of risk.

    Social protection instruments can protect individuals from negative life cycle changes. They can also adjust an individual’s livelihood in a way that makes the current phase of the life cycle less prone to vulnerability. Provision of social protection throughout the life cycle even has positive impacts on nonbeneficiaries within households. For example, available evidence suggests that providing social pensions increases expenditure on children within pensioner households (Willmore and Kidd 2008).

    Figure 1.2 depicts contingencies and risks that emerge during an individual’s life cycle. To a significant extent, social protection can mitigate the shocks that result from such contingencies.

    Figure 1.2: Contingencies and Risks at Various Stages of a Life Cycle

    Source: S. Kidd and C. de Paz. 2014. Report on Visit to Viet Nam to Support the Development of the Master Plan for Social Assistance Reform. New York: United Nations Development Programme.

    Many countries have integrated the life cycle approach into national social protection planning. For example, Bangladesh’s National Social Protection Strategy addresses contingencies during childhood, school age, working age, and old age, and also provides social protection for persons with disabilities (Planning Commission, Government of Bangladesh 2014).

    The life cycle approach to social protection is particularly effective in addressing the needs of informal sector workers who often face vulnerabilities and risks greater than their formal sector counterparts. This is because the life cycle approach allows the forms of social protection to be tailored to the vulnerabilities of particular demographic groups. Further, because the life cycle approach ensures that individuals are provided continuous coverage during all stages of life, it improves the level of social protection provided to the overall population.

    Development Planning Approach

    The development planning approach helps governments maximize the linkages between social protection and other components of the overall development effort such as education, health care, and provision of infrastructure. The assumption underlying the development planning approach is that the beneficial impact of social protection interventions at the household and community levels are maximized when they are integrated into the overall development planning framework. Embedding social protection into overall social and economic planning requires policy coordination at all levels of government, as well as between government and nongovernment entities such as service providers.

    The development planning matrix (Figure 1.3) depicts the impacts of social protection and related development objectives, as well as how these impacts can be maximized by integrating social protection into the overall development planning agenda. The three types of social protection initiatives (social assistance, social insurance, and labor market programs) form a subset of the policy instruments that comprise inputs into the development planning matrix. These three types of social protection initiatives directly address the needs of informal sector workers. However, they also contribute to beneficial social and economic development outcomes, which form the overall policy outputs presented in the right-hand column of the matrix.

    Figure 1.3: Development Planning Matrix

    Source: Authors.

    Integrated development planning through incorporating social protection for informal sector workers into overall development objectives allows these instruments to contribute to the achievement of overall development goals such as poverty alleviation, management of social risk, social inclusion, and human capital development. Thus, integrating social protection into the overall development effort links it with other development objectives, as it facilitates human capital development, livelihood development, and inclusive economic growth.

    The development planning matrix defines inputs as government policies, programs, and instruments that further national policy objectives (i.e., outputs). It thus emphasizes the linkages within and between sectors. The box shaded in the first quadrant shows how intrasector linkages (i.e., linkages between social protection initiatives) mutually strengthen the impact of all other social protection initiatives taken together in a way that facilitates achievement of social protection objectives. For example, when social transfers finance contributions to social health insurance for destitute households, household members are protected against catastrophic health shocks, for which simple cash transfers would be inadequate.

    Social protection initiatives also facilitate achievement of policy objectives in other sectors, such as promoting inclusive economic growth. Thus, a national coordinating mechanism that plans, prioritizes, and integrates social protection policies and initiatives in a coordinated fashion also deepens the impact of all social protection initiatives taken together. It does this by maximizing the likelihood of achieving social protection policy objectives, while at the same time minimizing associated risks and costs.

    The development planning framework also recognizes the potential for intersector impacts. For example, social protection programs that operate at the individual and household levels can complement one other, thus producing synergies that produce broader beneficial macroeconomic impacts. The Government of Indonesia recognizes the benefits of such synergies. As a result, it has delegated all aspects of development planning including social protection to the Ministry of National Development Planning (Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Nasional [BAPPENAS]). BAPPENAS is responsible for ensuring coherence between institutional arrangements and financing that relate to social protection, as well as ensuring coherence among all development initiatives in Indonesia. It is also responsible for coordinating development partner and donor funding of all development initiatives, including those that relate to social protection (BAPPENAS, Government of Indonesia 2016).

    Benefit Portability

    One of the most pressing policy objectives for social protection coverage for informal workers in Asia is benefit portability or the ability to preserve, maintain, and transfer vested social security rights or rights in the process of being vested, independent of nationality and country of residence (Avato, Koettl, and Sabates-Wheeler 2009). Portability of social protection benefits provides coverage to migrants, either by allowing them to access social protection benefits from their home country while abroad, or by obtaining access to social protection measures in their country of residence. Benefit portability minimizes the vulnerabilities that migrant workers face, thus protecting their basic human and social rights.

    The importance of establishing portable social protection benefits has become clear in recent years. Adopted at the 12th Association of Southeast Asian Nations Summit, the 2007 Declaration of the Promotion and Protection of the Rights of Migrant Workers includes provisions for promoting the welfare and upholding the dignity of migrant workers (Avato, Koettl, and Sabates-Wheeler 2009). This declaration recognizes that migrant workers have limited access to formal social protection benefits, thus ratifying the need for portable social protection benefits. Moreover, the declaration serves as a framework for designing portable social protection programs for all workers in the region, including those who work in the informal sector (Pasadilla 2011).

    Ultimately, labor migration benefits both the country of origin and the receiving country. The country of origin benefits from foreign exchange remittances, while the receiving country benefits from access to affordable labor. Yet little has been done to provide social protection for migrant populations, particularly those working in the informal sector.

    Agreements do exist for protecting formal sector workers in some countries in Asia. For example, Thailand extends social protection rights to legal migrants from Cambodia. Similarly, the Lao People’s Democratic Republic gives work permits to legal migrants from Cambodia for 2 years, extendable to 4 years (Samydorai 2012). Canada, Caribbean Community countries and areas, and New Zealand provide further examples of portable social protection benefits. Table 1.1 summarizes examples of social protection benefit portability worldwide. Although these examples primarily refer to formal sector workers, they can guide extension of such coverage to informal sector workers, including undocumented (and possibly illegal) informal sector migrant workers (Hall, Manajit, and Nga Na 2011).

    Table 1.1: Portable Social Protection Programs for Formal Sector Workers

    Sources: R. Holzmann and Y. Pouget. 2010. Social Protection for Temporary Migrant Workers: Conceptual Framework, Country Inventory, Assessment and Guidance. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTECA/Resources/tmporaryMigrantWorkers.pdf; Ministry of Overseas India Affairs, Government of India. Mahatma Gandhi Pravasi Suraksha Yojana (MGPSY). http://www.moia.gov.in/services.aspx?id1=409&id=m12&idp=409&mainid=73

    Ensuring Coherence at the Policy Level

    Coherence of social protection initiatives at the national policy level requires all social protection programs to be integrated, both with regard to their institutional arrangements and their financing. However, many of the region’s national social protection systems are fragmented, which in turn causes gaps in coverage and system inefficiencies.

    A number of government agencies—typically at different levels of government—implement social protection initiatives. As a result, these agencies often derive their funding from different sources. Without adequate communication between these agencies, parallel social protection programs often provide similar benefits to different geographic areas. This typically deprives some areas of the country of social protection coverage altogether; alternatively, it results in minimal coverage.

    Thailand’s social protection system provides an example of such fragmentation. Numerous government agencies are involved in programming and funding social initiatives in Thailand. These initiatives include the government officials’ pension system, Government Pension Fund, Civil Servant Medical Benefit Scheme, Workmen’s Compensation Fund, Social Security Fund, Private School Teacher Welfare Fund, Universal Coverage Scheme (UCS), Universal Non-Contributory Allowance for People with Disabilities, Universal Non-Contributory Allowance for Older People, Compulsory Migrant Health Insurance Scheme, and Education for All Policy (UN/RTG 2013). Similarly, Bangladesh implements more than 95 social protection programs, funded and administered by 30 different government ministries; however, no mechanism exists for coordinating between these programs or ministries (Planning Commission, Government of Bangladesh 2014).

    In many of the region’s developing countries, consolidating the social protection function by involving fewer ministries or finding ways to improve coordination between ministries would progress both the coverage and efficiency of social protection, without adding to the fiscal burden of the country. Another solution is to make a single government agency responsible for overall coordination and efficiency of the social protection system, as in Indonesia with BAPPENAS. Thus, although Indonesia’s social protection programs are implemented by a number of government ministries, making BAPPENAS responsible for coordinating these efforts mitigates the adverse effects of program fragmentation (Satriana and Schmitt 2012).

    Designing and Delivering Social Protection Programs for Informal Sector Workers: The Program Level

    As with the policy level discussed previously, efficient implementation of national social protection policy requires coherence at the program level. This means providing individuals with continuous coverage across all ages and income groups. Operationally, this denotes designing national social protection systems that respond to the particular risks and vulnerabilities faced by the populations that these systems serve, and putting into place fiscally sustainable programs that address these risks and vulnerabilities over time. The two best mechanisms for achieving this objective are the life cycle and development planning frameworks for designing social protection programs described earlier.

    As for informal sector workers, addressing the particular risks and vulnerabilities that they face requires that social protection programs are designed and financed in a way that enables them to reach marginalized populations. That said, designing and implementing social protection programs for informal sector workers is more complicated than for formal sector workers, due to financing and appropriateness.

    Regarding financing, the fact that work in the informal sector is not taxed raises the issue of how such programs can be financed in a way that makes them sustainable over the long term. With regard to appropriateness, the inherent heterogeneity of the informal sector makes designing social protection programs that target this sector particularly complex, as few programs adequately respond to all risks of all individuals and households in the sector.

    Some design considerations that address the issues of financing and appropriateness are described.

    Social Protection Initiatives

    Social protection initiatives are generally of three types: (i) noncontributory social assistance, (ii) contributory insurance programs, and (iii) labor market programs. Each of these types of initiatives comprises a broad array of instruments that can be used to mitigate risk and reduce the impact of negative shocks faced by informal sector workers (Figure 1.4).

    Figure 1.4: Instruments Comprising the Three Types of Social Protection Initiatives

    Source: T. McKinley and S. W. Handayani. 2013. The Social Protection Index: Assessing Results for Asia and the Pacific. Manila: Asian Development Bank, p. 5.

    Social Assistance

    Because few countries operate social protection programs that directly target informal sector workers, coverage is mostly extended through social assistance (Cook and Pincus 2014). Social assistance is generally delivered to informal sector workers through social transfers and social services.

    Social assistance helps manage risk by (i) reducing poverty that results from shocks; (ii) directly reducing vulnerabilities; and (iii) strengthening the coping mechanisms used by individuals, communities, and countries to address such shocks. Social assistance can also promote productive risk taking, such as enterprise development or investment in human capital. Both stimulate the economy at the local and national levels. Because of this, several countries in Asia have incorporated social assistance programs into their overall social protection systems (Table 1.2). This helps ensure that resources and infrastructure that decrease poverty and increase resilience to shocks are available to all members of the population, including informal sector workers.

    Table 1.2: Examples of National Social Protection Systems Incorporating Comprehensive Social Assistance Programs

    Sources: Planning Commission, Government of Bangladesh. 2014. National Social Protection Strategy (NSPS) of Bangladesh. http://www.plancomm.gov.bd//upload/2014/NSPS.pdf; Indian National Social Assistance Programme. http://nsap.nic.in/

    Poverty-targeted transfers. Many social transfers are poverty targeted. Such transfers provide cash or productive assets to individuals or households whose income falls below a certain threshold. However, rather than outright gifts, social transfers should, in fact, be used as a poverty alleviation tool. By ensuring at least a minimum standard of living for beneficiaries, they are able to take on productive risks and to mitigate the negative effects of shocks to the livelihood of a beneficiary household. Because informal sector workers living in poverty are exposed to greater risks and vulnerabilities than their formal sector counterparts, the risk management function of social assistance is of particular importance to this population. Further, the incidence of relative poverty is greater in the informal sector than in the formal sector. This is particularly true of informal sector agriculture workers, who face the highest risk of poverty (Heintz and Vanek 2007). Table 1.3 lists examples of conditional and unconditional poverty-targeted transfer mechanisms that meet the needs of informal sector workers.

    Table 1.3: Examples of Poverty-Targeted Transfer Schemes

    4Ps = Pantawid Pamilyang Pilipino Program.

    Sources: N. Chaudhury, J. Friedman, and J. Onishi. 2013. Philippines Conditional Cash Transfer Program: Impact Evaluation 2012. http://pantawid.dswd.gov.ph/images/philippines_conditional_cash_transfer_program_impact_evaluation_2012.pdf; S. Nazara and S. K. Rahayu. 2013. Program Keluarga Harapan (PKH): Indonesian Conditional Cash Transfer Programme. International Policy Centre for Inclusive Growth Research Briefs. No. 42. http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/IPCPolicyResearchBrief42.pdf; J. Golan, T. Sicular, and N. Umapathi. 2014. Any Guarantees? China’s Rural Minimum Living Standard Guarantee Program. Social Protection and Labor Discussion Paper Series. No. 1423. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/19976/900300NWP0P132085299B00PUBLIC001423.pdf?sequence=1

    Grants for children and families. These grants are provided to both individuals and households with children to reduce poverty and vulnerability and to improve children’s access to basic services. Such transfers take the form of unconditional family allowances and child grants, or cash transfers dependent on fulfilling stated conditions that deepen the development impact of social transfers. For informal sector workers, parents are afforded a minimum level of income to provide for their children, even when the household faces income instability. By focusing on children, these grants encourage expansion of the stock of human capital and allow recipient children to be more productive workers later in life.

    These grants thus produce a positive economic impact at the national level. Investing in early childhood development through these grants is particularly beneficial for countries with populations of young average age, as they stand to benefit when the cohort that has received such grants enters the labor force. Such grants would thus be particularly beneficial to South Asian countries in which the average age of the population has not yet begun to rise at a significant rate (ADB 2011). Table 1.4 lists examples of grants for children and families that are either already in operation, or are proposed.

    Table 1.4: Examples of Grants for Children and Families

    Sources: T. Okubo. 2014. Nutritional Impact of the Child Grant: An Evidence from Karnali Zone, Nepal. UNICEF Nepal Working Paper Series. No. 3. http://www.un.org.np/sites/default/files/Nutritional_Impact_paper.pdf; A. Hodges et al. 2007. Child Benefits and Poverty Reduction: Evidence from Mongolia’s Child Money Programme. Maastricht University Graduate School of Governance Working Papers. No. 002. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1095717; United Nations Children’s Fund (UNICEF). 2014. UNICEF Welcomes Child Support Grant as Four Million Children under Six in Thailand Still Lack Adequate Social Protection. http://www.unicef.org/thailand/media_23401.html

    Social pensions. Social pensions are noncontributory transfers provided to individuals of old age that guarantee a minimum income. Social pensions are particularly important for informal sector workers, as they are typically denied access to contributory pensions, and often continue to be employed in old age. In many developing countries in Asia, older workers are typically employed in the informal sector in less-attractive jobs that pay wages less than those received by individuals still of working age (Kidd and Whitehouse 2009).

    Social pension programs bridge the gap in old age between those with access to contributory pension schemes and the means to participate in them, and those that lack both. Such schemes restore dignity to older persons by ensuring that they are not left in deep poverty and regarded as a burden by their families (Kidd and Whitehouse 2009). Social pensions have also been shown to offer benefits within the household itself. Older persons often share their pension with the rest of the household, thus reducing the financial burden associated with their care. The security of a minimum income later in life is also likely to lead to more productive spending of income during working age (Willmore and Kidd 2008). Such implications are particularly important for informal sector workers. By reducing the need to provide for elderly relatives or to save intensively for their own future, social pensions allow working-age individuals to invest in productive assets or skills.

    Many higher-income countries in Asia are experiencing rapid aging of their populations due to falling fertility rates and increased longevity (ADB 2011). Under such conditions, social protection should increasingly focus on providing for individuals in old age. This is already occurring in these countries where pensions are an increasingly important component of the national social protection system. Table 1.5 lists a number of examples of noncontributory social pensions currently operating in developing countries in Asia.

    Table 1.5: Examples of Noncontributory Social Pensions

    Sources: W. Suwandra and D. Wesumperuma. 2012. Development of the Old-Age Allowance System in Thailand: Challenges and Poverty Implications. In S. W. Handayani and B. Babajanian, eds. Social Protection for Older Persons: Social Pensions in Asia. Manila: ADB; M. Samson. 2012. Nepal’s Senior Citizens’ Allowance: A Model of Universalism in a Low-Income Country Context. In S. W. Handayani and B. Babajanian, eds. Social Protection for Older Persons: Social Pensions in Asia. Manila: ADB; G. T. Long and D. Wesumperuma. 2013. Some Notes on Social Pensions in Viet Nam. International Policy Centre for Inclusive Growth One Pager. No. 210. http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/IPCOnePager210.pdf

    Noncontributory health care. Access to health care is often the first security that poor and vulnerable people seek. Further, universal health care is recognized as a human right, and a key factor in stimulating labor productivity and overall economic growth. Such findings make universal health care a cost-effective endeavor (Rys 2013).

    Extending access to basic health care to informal sector workers in a way that guarantees their security and livelihood is an important feature of social protection for the informal sector, given that work environments in the informal sector often pose a threat to workers’ health. However, the scale of the assistance provided must be sufficient to ensure that informal sector workers can afford basic health care services, and that the resulting improved level of general health of the informal sector workforce is sufficient to achieve a development impact commensurate with the cost of such a

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1